Appendix to Technology Transfer and Spillovers in International Joint Ventures

Σχετικά έγγραφα
HOMEWORK 4 = G. In order to plot the stress versus the stretch we define a normalized stretch:

CHAPTER 25 SOLVING EQUATIONS BY ITERATIVE METHODS

Homework 3 Solutions

Phys460.nb Solution for the t-dependent Schrodinger s equation How did we find the solution? (not required)

C.S. 430 Assignment 6, Sample Solutions

Statistical Inference I Locally most powerful tests

2 Composition. Invertible Mappings

3.4 SUM AND DIFFERENCE FORMULAS. NOTE: cos(α+β) cos α + cos β cos(α-β) cos α -cos β

EE512: Error Control Coding

Matrices and Determinants

derivation of the Laplacian from rectangular to spherical coordinates

ST5224: Advanced Statistical Theory II

Appendix S1 1. ( z) α βc. dβ β δ β

Example Sheet 3 Solutions

Risk! " #$%&'() *!'+,'''## -. / # $

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates

Section 8.3 Trigonometric Equations

Math221: HW# 1 solutions

Econ 2110: Fall 2008 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8 questions or comments to Dan Fetter 1

Other Test Constructions: Likelihood Ratio & Bayes Tests

Finite Field Problems: Solutions

Ordinal Arithmetic: Addition, Multiplication, Exponentiation and Limit

Every set of first-order formulas is equivalent to an independent set

DESIGN OF MACHINERY SOLUTION MANUAL h in h 4 0.

Απόκριση σε Μοναδιαία Ωστική Δύναμη (Unit Impulse) Απόκριση σε Δυνάμεις Αυθαίρετα Μεταβαλλόμενες με το Χρόνο. Απόστολος Σ.

Approximation of distance between locations on earth given by latitude and longitude

Reminders: linear functions

Practice Exam 2. Conceptual Questions. 1. State a Basic identity and then verify it. (a) Identity: Solution: One identity is csc(θ) = 1

Concrete Mathematics Exercises from 30 September 2016

A Note on Intuitionistic Fuzzy. Equivalence Relation

Solutions to Exercise Sheet 5

Section 7.6 Double and Half Angle Formulas

Exercises to Statistics of Material Fatigue No. 5

CHAPTER 101 FOURIER SERIES FOR PERIODIC FUNCTIONS OF PERIOD

Homework 8 Model Solution Section

Problem Set 3: Solutions

Srednicki Chapter 55

SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES G11LMA Linear Mathematics Examination Solutions

Second Order Partial Differential Equations

ΕΛΛΗΝΙΚΗ ΔΗΜΟΚΡΑΤΙΑ ΠΑΝΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΙΟ ΚΡΗΤΗΣ. Ψηφιακή Οικονομία. Διάλεξη 10η: Basics of Game Theory part 2 Mαρίνα Μπιτσάκη Τμήμα Επιστήμης Υπολογιστών

Nowhere-zero flows Let be a digraph, Abelian group. A Γ-circulation in is a mapping : such that, where, and : tail in X, head in

SCITECH Volume 13, Issue 2 RESEARCH ORGANISATION Published online: March 29, 2018

Partial Differential Equations in Biology The boundary element method. March 26, 2013

Exercises 10. Find a fundamental matrix of the given system of equations. Also find the fundamental matrix Φ(t) satisfying Φ(0) = I. 1.

Tridiagonal matrices. Gérard MEURANT. October, 2008

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval

6.1. Dirac Equation. Hamiltonian. Dirac Eq.

Second Order RLC Filters

Coefficient Inequalities for a New Subclass of K-uniformly Convex Functions

4.6 Autoregressive Moving Average Model ARMA(1,1)

ΚΥΠΡΙΑΚΗ ΕΤΑΙΡΕΙΑ ΠΛΗΡΟΦΟΡΙΚΗΣ CYPRUS COMPUTER SOCIETY ΠΑΓΚΥΠΡΙΟΣ ΜΑΘΗΤΙΚΟΣ ΔΙΑΓΩΝΙΣΜΟΣ ΠΛΗΡΟΦΟΡΙΚΗΣ 6/5/2006

CRASH COURSE IN PRECALCULUS

Main source: "Discrete-time systems and computer control" by Α. ΣΚΟΔΡΑΣ ΨΗΦΙΑΚΟΣ ΕΛΕΓΧΟΣ ΔΙΑΛΕΞΗ 4 ΔΙΑΦΑΝΕΙΑ 1

5. Choice under Uncertainty

Uniform Convergence of Fourier Series Michael Taylor

Inverse trigonometric functions & General Solution of Trigonometric Equations

1 String with massive end-points

k A = [k, k]( )[a 1, a 2 ] = [ka 1,ka 2 ] 4For the division of two intervals of confidence in R +

Strain gauge and rosettes

Problem Set 9 Solutions. θ + 1. θ 2 + cotθ ( ) sinθ e iφ is an eigenfunction of the ˆ L 2 operator. / θ 2. φ 2. sin 2 θ φ 2. ( ) = e iφ. = e iφ cosθ.

Depth versus Rigidity in the Design of International Trade Agreements. Leslie Johns

Mean-Variance Analysis

ΕΛΛΗΝΙΚΗ ΔΗΜΟΚΡΑΤΙΑ ΠΑΝΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΙΟ ΚΡΗΤΗΣ

Pg The perimeter is P = 3x The area of a triangle is. where b is the base, h is the height. In our case b = x, then the area is

Quadratic Expressions

Solution Series 9. i=1 x i and i=1 x i.

On a four-dimensional hyperbolic manifold with finite volume

Μηχανική Μάθηση Hypothesis Testing

Fractional Colorings and Zykov Products of graphs

The Simply Typed Lambda Calculus

ΚΥΠΡΙΑΚΗ ΕΤΑΙΡΕΙΑ ΠΛΗΡΟΦΟΡΙΚΗΣ CYPRUS COMPUTER SOCIETY ΠΑΓΚΥΠΡΙΟΣ ΜΑΘΗΤΙΚΟΣ ΔΙΑΓΩΝΙΣΜΟΣ ΠΛΗΡΟΦΟΡΙΚΗΣ 19/5/2007

forms This gives Remark 1. How to remember the above formulas: Substituting these into the equation we obtain with

= λ 1 1 e. = λ 1 =12. has the properties e 1. e 3,V(Y

Lecture 15 - Root System Axiomatics

The Probabilistic Method - Probabilistic Techniques. Lecture 7: The Janson Inequality

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM

F19MC2 Solutions 9 Complex Analysis

( y) Partial Differential Equations

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval

D Alembert s Solution to the Wave Equation

A Two-Sided Laplace Inversion Algorithm with Computable Error Bounds and Its Applications in Financial Engineering

2. Let H 1 and H 2 be Hilbert spaces and let T : H 1 H 2 be a bounded linear operator. Prove that [T (H 1 )] = N (T ). (6p)

ANSWERSHEET (TOPIC = DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS) COLLECTION #2. h 0 h h 0 h h 0 ( ) g k = g 0 + g 1 + g g 2009 =?

Jesse Maassen and Mark Lundstrom Purdue University November 25, 2013

Ψηφιακή Οικονομία. Διάλεξη 11η: Markets and Strategic Interaction in Networks Mαρίνα Μπιτσάκη Τμήμα Επιστήμης Υπολογιστών

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM

1) Formulation of the Problem as a Linear Programming Model

Congruence Classes of Invertible Matrices of Order 3 over F 2

Appendix to On the stability of a compressible axisymmetric rotating flow in a pipe. By Z. Rusak & J. H. Lee

Fourier Series. MATH 211, Calculus II. J. Robert Buchanan. Spring Department of Mathematics

6.3 Forecasting ARMA processes

MA 342N Assignment 1 Due 24 February 2016

ΕΛΛΗΝΙΚΗ ΔΗΜΟΚΡΑΤΙΑ ΠΑΝΕΠΙΣΤΗΜΙΟ ΚΡΗΤΗΣ. Ψηφιακή Οικονομία. Διάλεξη 7η: Consumer Behavior Mαρίνα Μπιτσάκη Τμήμα Επιστήμης Υπολογιστών

Numerical Analysis FMN011

Lecture 13 - Root Space Decomposition II

Assalamu `alaikum wr. wb.

9.09. # 1. Area inside the oval limaçon r = cos θ. To graph, start with θ = 0 so r = 6. Compute dr

Differentiation exercise show differential equation

Lecture 2. Soundness and completeness of propositional logic

Transcript:

Appendix to Technology Transfer and Spillovers in International Joint Ventures Thomas Müller Monika Schnitzer Published in Journal of International Economics, 2006, Volume 68, 456-468 Bundestanstalt für Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin), International/Financial Markets Department, Georg-von- Boeselager-Str. 25, 53117 Bonn, Germany, Tel.: +49 228 4108 3732, Fax.: +49 228 4108 63732, e-mail: Thomas.Mueller3@bafin.de Department of Economics,University of Munich, Akademiestr. 1/III, 80799 Munich, Germany, Tel.: +49-89-2180 2217, Fax.: +49-89-2180 2767, e-mail: schnitzer@lrz.uni-muenchen.de

Proof of Result 1 MNE maximizes U MNE = qr q(1 )βs K(q). Given the assumptions on K(q) the optimal level of investment q is uniquely characterized by the following first order condition: K (q) = R 1 βs. Using the implicit function theorem we can show that dq = 1 β K (q) = (1 )β K (q) < 0 dq ( (1 )) = βs 2 K (q) = βs 2 K (q) > 0 Using these results we can show that du MNE dq dq R (1 )βs q(1 )β K (q) [R (1 )βs K (q)] q(1 )β = q(1 )β < 0 Furthermore du HC dq (1 )(R + S) + q(1 ) (1 ) K (q) (1 )[R + S K (q)] + q(1 ) 1 (1 )[R βs K (q) ( ) } {{ } (1 ) [ 1 βs + S] } {{} (+) + q(1 ) (+) + 1 βs + S] + q(1 ) Note that for S = 0, the first derivative for U HC is positive, whereas for S getting very large, the derivative gets negative. Hence, HC s payoff is maximized at S > 0. 1

Finally, note that d(u MNE + U HC ) = q(1 )(1 β) + dq (1 ) [ 1 βs + S] } {{} ( ) (+) For β 1, this derivative is negative for all S, whereas for β < 1 it is positive for S = 0 and it gets negative for large S. Hence welfare is maximized for S > 0. Proof of Result 2 Using the results from above we can show that du MNE = qr + dq dq dq R + qβs (1 )βs K(q) K (q) [R (1 )βs K (q)] +q(r + βs) K(q) > 0 Furthermore, du HC dq (1 )(R + S) q(r + S) + K(q) (1 ) K (q) 1 (1 )[R βs K (q) + 1 βs + S] [q(r + S) K(q)] (1 )[ 1 βs + S] [q(r + S) K(q)] (+) (+) Note that for = 1, this derivative is negative. For 0 it gets positive. Hence, HC s payoff is maximized at < 1. Finally, note that d(u MNE + U HC ) = q(β 1)S) + dq (+) (1 ) [(1 )βs + S] This expression is positive for β 1 and welfare is maximized for < 1 if β < 1. Lemma A 2

For any (0, 1), HC s maximization problem has a unique interior solution T () ( (1 ) β β+ S, R 1 βs). Proof of Lemma A We first show that HC s profit function is strictly concave in T. theorem, dqt (T ) dt = 1 K (q T ) < 0. Differentiating U T HC with respect to T we get dt T (T ) dt = 1 [ K (q T ) (1 )[R T K (q T ) +S] + T + qt (T ) = 1 βs by (7) (1 ) β β + ] S + T + q T (T ). d 2 UHC T = 1 [ ] K β + [(1 )β S + T ] + 1 + < 0. dt 2 K [K ] 2 By the implicit function Hence, the optimal T () must be unique. Furthermore, it is never optimal to choose T R 1 βs, because this would imply qt (T, ) = 0 and U T HC = 0, while a strictly positive payoff can be obtained by choosing T < R 1 βs. Finally, it cannot be optimal to choose T = T (1 ) β β+ S. To see this note that at T = T we have q T (T, ) > 0.Thus, dt T =T = q T (T, ) > 0. Hence, if > 0, a strictly higher payoff can be obtained by choosing T > T. Proof of Lemma 1 By the implicit function theorem we can show that dq T = 1 [ 1 K β + dt ]. 3

Using again the implicit function theorem and taking account of the direct effect of an increase in S on q, i.e. 1 1 K β, we find that dt K dq T [K ] 2 [(1 ) β β+ S + T ] + dqt β β+ (1 ) + dqt dt = K dq T β β+ [(1 ) S + T [K ] 2 dt ] + dqt + dqt dt dt ( ) 1 K = β [(1 ) β β+ S + T ] + 1 + [K ] 2 β K [(1 ) β β+ S + T [K ] 2 ] + 1 + =A>0 ( ) 1 = β A < 0, with A < 1 if β > 1. Proof of Result 3 Using Lemma 1, we can show that dq T = 1 1 β[a 1]. K Differentiating U T MNE and U T HC with respect to S and re-arranging we get: du T MNE T T = q T dt qt (1 )β + dqt [R T K dq T (q)] (1 )βs } = 1 βs by (7) {{ } = q T (1 )β[a 1]. [ +S] + T + qt (1 ) + dt = 1 βs by (7) (1 )[R T K (q) [ (1 ) β β + ] S + T + q T (1 )[1 βa]. ] Note that for β > 1 we get βa > 1 and vice versa. Summarizing the effects: (i) β = 1 A = 1 dt (ii) β < 1 A > 1 dt dqt < 0, dqt < 0,, du MNE T, du MNE T, = 0, d(u T MNE +U T HC ) = 0, > 0, d(u T MNE +U T HC ) > 0 4

(iii) β > 1 A < 1 dt dqt < 0,, du MNE T, < 0, d(u T MNE +U T HC ) < 0 For β = 1 we have dqt = 0. Thus, it follows from equation (7) that for β = 1 we must have T (; S) = T (, 0) 1 S, where T characterizes the optimal choice of T for S = 0. Proof of Lemma 2 By the implicit function theorem, it is straightforward to show that dq T = 1 [ dt K 1 ] βs. 2 Using again the implicit function theorem and taking account of the direct effect of an increase in on q T (T, ), i.e. 1 K 1 2 βs, we can show that dt = 1 K βs 2 + [(1 ) β β+ [K ] 2 K [(1 ) β β+ [K ] 2 S + T ] + 1 2 + 2 β S + T ] + 1 + + } {{ } =B>0 q S (T ) K [(1 ) β β+ [K ] 3 S + T ] + (1 + ) 1 K }{{ } =D>0 = 1 2 βsb + D > 0, withb < 1 for β > 1. Proof of Result 4 Differentiating UHC T with respect to and re-arranging we get: T (1 )[R T K (q T ) +S] + T = 1 βs by (7) + K(q T ) q T [R T + S] = 1 [ dt K 1 ] βs 2 + qt dt β + (1 )β S + T }{{ } =K q T by (8) 5 + qt dt

+ K(q T ) q T [R T + S] = K(q T ) q T [R T + S] + q T 1 βs. (A1) <0 >0 A marginal increase of reduces HC s share of total surplus, q T [R T ] K(q T ), and reduces the received spillover, q T S. On the other hand, a marginal increase of induces HC to increase total taxation by dt dqt and it induces MNE to change investment by. Both effects sum up to q T 1 βs, which is basically the direct effect of an increase in on the investment qt. This effect may dominate and thus HC may prefer to increase, if β is sufficiently large. Note that (A1) can be positive only if β > 1. To see this, note further that MNE will choose q T > 0 only if U T MNE > 0, i.e. q T [R T ] q T (1 )βs K(q T ) I > 0. Condition (A1) is positive if, after re-arranging, we have q T [R T ] q T βs + q T S K(q T ) < 0. Both conditions can be fulfilled simultaneously only if β > 1. Differentiating U T MNE with respect to and re-arranging we get: du T MNE = q T [R T + βs] K(q T ) q T dt + dqt [ R T K (q T ) ] } = 1 βs by (7) {{ } = q T [R T + βs] K(q T ) >0 dqt (1 )βs q T dt } {{ } >0. (A2) Thus, the impact of on MNE s payoff may be ambiguous. A marginal increase of increases MNE s share of the total net payoff, q T [R T ] K(q T ), and reduces the loss due to the spillover, q T βs. On the other hand, a marginal increase of induces HC to increase total taxes by dt, of which MNE has to pay the share in case of a successful project, which happens with probability q T. If is close enough to 0, the second effect vanishes and MNE always 6

prefers to increase. However, if is sufficiently large, the second effect may dominate. The effect of a change of on total surplus is given by d(u T MNE + U T HC) = q T 1 βs qt dt + qt (β 1)S = q T 1 βs[1 B] q T D + q T (β 1)S. (A3) } {{} < 0 for >0 < 0 for β < 1 β < 1 By proof of Lemma 1 and Result 3 we know that for β = 1, T (, S) = T (, 0) 1 S and thus q T (; S) = q (, 0). Hence, equations (A1), (A2), and (A3), and therefore the effects of a decrease in are the same for β = 1 and for S = 0. Summarizing the effects: (i) β = 1 dt (ii) β < 1 dt dqt > 0, dqt > 0, < 0, du T MNE < 0, du T MNE < 0, d(u T MNE +U T HC ) < 0. < 0, d(u T MNE +U T HC ) < 0. (iii) β > 1 dt dqt > 0, du T MNE d(u T MNE +U T HC ) < 0. We prove by example that there indeed exist cases with the properties described in the Result. Consider the following cost function: K(q) = 1 1 q q. For = 0.98, R = 40, and S = 3 the following results are obtained for different values of β: du T MNE d(u T MNE +U T HC ) q T T U T MNE U T HC β = 0.3-0.25-4.11-4.36 0.65866 32.40 2.669 21.434 β = 1-0.07-2.72-2.79 0.65855 32.36 2.665 21.406 β = 1.2-0.02-2.32-2.34 0.65852 32.35 2.664 21.398 β = 3 0.43 1.23 1.67 0.65823 32.25 2.655 21.327 Thus, for large values of, there exist cases where MNE s payoff increases as decreases. This result can be obtained independently of the efficiency of a spillover β. For β > 1 there exist cases where HC s payoff and the efficiency of the project increase as increases. This is the 7

case for β = 3 in the example. For = 1 and R = 40 we get: du T MNE d(u T MNE +U T HC ) q T T U T MNE U T HC = 1 - - - 0.65838 32.51 2.664 21.352 Hence, in some cases HC benefits and the efficiency of the project is maximized if ownership is not shared. The intuition for this is easy to see for the extreme example of β being so large that the optimal q is chosen equal to zero for any < 1. In this case, HC s payoff is maximized by choosing = 1. This induces MNE to choose a positive q and hence allows HC to enjoy a positive payoff through taxation. Lemma B For any (0, 1), HC s payoff is maximized at M (), with (a) M () (0, ), if R > 1 (b) M () ( 1 βs R, ), if R 1 (c) M = 0, if R 1 βs otherwise. Proof of Lemma B βs and d2 UHC M dm 2 M=M < 0, or βs, d2 UHC M dm 2 M=M < 0, and UHC(M M ) > 0, or The optimal level of investment q is characterized by the following first order condition: K (q M ) = R + M 1 βs. (A4) By the implicit function theorem, dqm (M) dm = 1 K (q M ) > 0. Differentiating U M HC with respect to M we get duhc M dm M dm = (1 ) R + M K (q M ) +S + qm (1 ) C (M) = 1 βs by (9) β + (1 )β S + q M (M)(1 ) C (M). 1 K (q M ) 8

d 2 UHC M = 1 [ ] K β + (1 )β S (1 ) C (M). dm 2 K [K ] 2 Hence, HC s payoff is maximized at M (), if d2 U M HC dm 2 M=M < 0 and if moreover U M HC(M ) > 0. Given the assumptions on C(M) there must exist an upper bound for M. If < 1 and R > 1 βs, it is never optimal to choose M = 0. To see this note that in this case q M > 0 and thus du M HC dm = M 1 K (q M ) β + (1 )β S + q M (M)(1 ) > 0. Hence, if (0, 1), a strictly higher payoff can be obtained by choosing M > 0. If < 1 and R 1 βs, it follows from equation (9) that q = 0 for all M 1 βs R. Hence, HC chooses M ( 1 βs R, ) if U M HC(M ) > 0 and M = 0 otherwise. Proof of Lemma 3 By the implicit function theorem we can show that dq M = 1 [ 1 K β dm ]. Using again the implicit function theorem and taking account of the direct effect of an increase in S on q M (M, ), i.e. 1 1 K βs, we find that dm = K (1 ) β β+ dq M [K ] 2 K dq M [K ] 2 dm S + dqm β β+ (1 ) dm (1 ) β β+ S + dqm (1 ) C dm = 1 K β (1 ) β β+ S + [K ] 2 β K (1 ) β β+ > 0. S (1 ) + K [K ] 2 C =E>0 + dqm (1 ) The last inequality follows from the fact that the denominator has to be positive by Lemma B if HC s payoff is maximized at M (). 9

Proof of Result 5 From Lemma 3 it follows dq M = 1 K 1 β[e 1] where E is defined above in the Proof of Lemma 3. Note that E > 1 if β > (1 ) + K C and vice versa. It is straightforward to see that E > 1 is compatible with both β > 1 and β < 1, and vice versa for E < 1. Differentiating U M MNE and U M HC with respect to S and re-arranging we get: du M MNE M [R + M K (q M )] dqm (1 )βs } = 1 βs by (A4) {{ } + q M dm qm (1 )β = q M (1 )β[e 1] < 0. du M HC M (1 ) R + M K (q M ) +S + qm (1 ) dm βs by (A4) = 1 + q M (1 ) C (M) dm = 1 K [ 1 β dm ] (1 ) β β + S + q M (1 ) dm + q M (1 ) C (M) dm = 1 (1 ) 2 ( ) β β + βs + q M (1 ) < 0. K The effect of a change in S on total surplus is given by d(u M MNE + U M HC) = q M (1 )β[e 1] 1 (1 ) 2 K + q M (1 ) < 0. β β + βs 10

Proof of Lemma 4 By the implicit function theorem we can show that dq M = 1 [ dm K + 1 ] βs. 2 Using again the implicit function theorem and taking account of the direct effect of an increase in on q M (M, ), i.e. 1 K 1 2 βs, we can show that dm = 1 K [(1 ) β β+ S] + 2 + 2 [K βs ] 2 β 2 K [(1 ) β β+ S] (1 ) + K [K ] 2 C q M (M) K [(1 ) β β+ < 0. S] (1 ) 1 + C [K ] 3 K The last inequality follows from the fact that the denominator has to be positive by Lemma B if HC s payoff is maximized at M (). Proof of Result 6 Differentiating U M HC and U M MNE with respect to and re-arranging we get: du M HC M = 1 K (1 ) R + M K (q M ) +S + qm (1 ) dm = 1 βs by (9) C (M) dm + K(qM ) q M [R + M + S] [ dm + 1 ] βs (1 ) β β + S 2 + dm [ q M (1 ) C (M) ] + K(q M ) q M [R + M + S] = K(q M ) q M [R + M + S] + 1 β + (1 )β } {{ } <0 } K {{} >0 βs 2. (A5) 3 Thus, the impact of on HC s payoff is, independently of the efficiency of the spillover β, ambiguous. A marginal increase of reduces HC s share of total surplus, K(q M ) q M [R + M ] and reduces the received spillover q M S. On the other hand, a marginal increase of induces HC 11

to reduce its investment in infrastructure by dm and it induces MNE to change investment by dq M. Both effects sum up to the second expression in (A5). This effect may dominate depending on the exact nature of investment costs. du M MNE = q M [R + M + βs] K(q M ) + q M dm + dqm [R + M K (q M )] dqm (1 )βs } = 1 βs by (A4) {{ } = q M [R + M + βs] K(q M ) >0 + q M dm } {{ } <0. The impact of on MNE s payoff may also be ambiguous. A marginal increase of increases MNE s share of total net payoff, q M [R + M ] K(q M ) and reduces the loss due to the spillover by q M βs. On the other hand, a marginal increase of induces HC to reduce its investment in infrastructure by dm, of which MNE enjoys the share in case of a successful project, which happens with probability q M. If is close to 0, the second effect vanishes and MNE always prefers to increase. However, if is sufficiently large, the second effect may dominate. The effect of a change in on total surplus is given by d(u M MNE + U M HC) = q M (β 1)S + 1 β + (1 )β βs 2 K < 0 for }{{ 3 } >0 β < 1 + q M dm } {{ } <0. Summarizing the effects: (i) S = 0 dm dqm < 0, < 0, du M MNE du M HC < 0, d(u M MNE +U M HC ) < 0. (ii) S > 0 dm dqm < 0, du M MNE du M HC d(u M MNE +U M HC ) < 0. We prove by example that there indeed exist cases with the properties described in the Result. Consider the following cost functions: K(q) = 1 3 q3 and C(M) = M 2. For = 0.98, R = 0.1, and S = 20 the following results are obtained for different values of β: 12

du M MNE du M HC d(u M MNE +U M HC ) q M M U M MNE U M HC β = 0.4-0.92-4.62-5.54 0.423 0.242 0.05 0.11 β = 0.8 0.03 4.32 4.35 0.315 0.326 0.02 0.02 β = 0.9 - - - 0 0 0 0 Thus, for large values of, there exist cases where MNE s payoff increases as decreases. Moreover, there exist cases where HC s payoff and the efficiency of the project increase as increases. As the example highlights this can be the case even for an efficient spillover. For β = 0.9 sharing of ownership with = 0.98 results in no investment by both parties. However, for = 0.99, R = 0.1, and S = 20 we get: du M MNE du M HC d(u M MNE +U M HC ) q M M U M MNE U M HC β = 0.9 0.19 0.18 0.37 0.298 0.171 0.02 0.03 13