Managing Production-Inventory Systems with Scarce Resources

Σχετικά έγγραφα
Every set of first-order formulas is equivalent to an independent set

Ordinal Arithmetic: Addition, Multiplication, Exponentiation and Limit

ST5224: Advanced Statistical Theory II

C.S. 430 Assignment 6, Sample Solutions

EE512: Error Control Coding

Uniform Convergence of Fourier Series Michael Taylor

Problem Set 3: Solutions

2 Composition. Invertible Mappings

Example Sheet 3 Solutions

Math 446 Homework 3 Solutions. (1). (i): Reverse triangle inequality for metrics: Let (X, d) be a metric space and let x, y, z X.

( ) ( t) ( 0) ( ) dw w. = = β. Then the solution of (1.1) is easily found to. wt = t+ t. We generalize this to the following nonlinear differential

Appendix. The solution begins with Eq. (2.15) from the text, which we repeat here for 1, (A.1)

ORDINAL ARITHMETIC JULIAN J. SCHLÖDER

4.6 Autoregressive Moving Average Model ARMA(1,1)

Necessary and sufficient conditions for oscillation of first order nonlinear neutral differential equations

Homework 3 Solutions

Online Appendix to Measuring the Bullwhip Effect: Discrepancy and Alignment between Information and Material Flows

Lecture 2. Soundness and completeness of propositional logic

A Two-Sided Laplace Inversion Algorithm with Computable Error Bounds and Its Applications in Financial Engineering

A Note on Intuitionistic Fuzzy. Equivalence Relation

Math221: HW# 1 solutions

Finite Field Problems: Solutions

Second Order Partial Differential Equations

Matrices and Determinants

Appendix S1 1. ( z) α βc. dβ β δ β

Statistical Inference I Locally most powerful tests

Solution Series 9. i=1 x i and i=1 x i.

Practice Exam 2. Conceptual Questions. 1. State a Basic identity and then verify it. (a) Identity: Solution: One identity is csc(θ) = 1

Lecture 21: Properties and robustness of LSE

An Introduction to Signal Detection and Estimation - Second Edition Chapter II: Selected Solutions

( ) ( ) ( ) Fourier series. ; m is an integer. r(t) is periodic (T>0), r(t+t) = r(t), t Fundamental period T 0 = smallest T. Fundamental frequency ω

APPENDIX A DERIVATION OF JOINT FAILURE DENSITIES

HOMEWORK 4 = G. In order to plot the stress versus the stretch we define a normalized stretch:

F19MC2 Solutions 9 Complex Analysis

k A = [k, k]( )[a 1, a 2 ] = [ka 1,ka 2 ] 4For the division of two intervals of confidence in R +

The choice of an optimal LCSCR contract involves the choice of an x L. such that the supplier chooses the LCS option when x xl

6.1. Dirac Equation. Hamiltonian. Dirac Eq.

Fractional Colorings and Zykov Products of graphs

Homomorphism in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Automata

w o = R 1 p. (1) R = p =. = 1

Reminders: linear functions

Phys460.nb Solution for the t-dependent Schrodinger s equation How did we find the solution? (not required)

5. Choice under Uncertainty

1. Introduction and Preliminaries.

Nonlinear Analysis: Modelling and Control, 2013, Vol. 18, No. 4,

Coefficient Inequalities for a New Subclass of K-uniformly Convex Functions

A Simple Version of the Lucas Model

Quadratic Expressions

The challenges of non-stable predicates

Other Test Constructions: Likelihood Ratio & Bayes Tests

On Strong Product of Two Fuzzy Graphs

Intuitionistic Fuzzy Ideals of Near Rings

Online Appendix I. 1 1+r ]}, Bψ = {ψ : Y E A S S}, B W = +(1 s)[1 m (1,0) (b, e, a, ψ (0,a ) (e, a, s); q, ψ, W )]}, (29) exp( U(d,a ) (i, x; q)

Main source: "Discrete-time systems and computer control" by Α. ΣΚΟΔΡΑΣ ΨΗΦΙΑΚΟΣ ΕΛΕΓΧΟΣ ΔΙΑΛΕΞΗ 4 ΔΙΑΦΑΝΕΙΑ 1

= {{D α, D α }, D α }. = [D α, 4iσ µ α α D α µ ] = 4iσ µ α α [Dα, D α ] µ.

Strain gauge and rosettes

Exercise 2: The form of the generalized likelihood ratio

Inverse trigonometric functions & General Solution of Trigonometric Equations

Concrete Mathematics Exercises from 30 September 2016

Tridiagonal matrices. Gérard MEURANT. October, 2008

CHAPTER 25 SOLVING EQUATIONS BY ITERATIVE METHODS

Generating Set of the Complete Semigroups of Binary Relations

Nowhere-zero flows Let be a digraph, Abelian group. A Γ-circulation in is a mapping : such that, where, and : tail in X, head in

Linear singular perturbations of hyperbolic-parabolic type

2. Let H 1 and H 2 be Hilbert spaces and let T : H 1 H 2 be a bounded linear operator. Prove that [T (H 1 )] = N (T ). (6p)

ANSWERSHEET (TOPIC = DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS) COLLECTION #2. h 0 h h 0 h h 0 ( ) g k = g 0 + g 1 + g g 2009 =?

Lecture 2: Dirac notation and a review of linear algebra Read Sakurai chapter 1, Baym chatper 3

CRASH COURSE IN PRECALCULUS

Solutions to Exercise Sheet 5

Congruence Classes of Invertible Matrices of Order 3 over F 2

Appendix to On the stability of a compressible axisymmetric rotating flow in a pipe. By Z. Rusak & J. H. Lee

A General Note on δ-quasi Monotone and Increasing Sequence

SOME PROPERTIES OF FUZZY REAL NUMBERS

F A S C I C U L I M A T H E M A T I C I

Second Order RLC Filters

Section 8.3 Trigonometric Equations

Bounding Nonsplitting Enumeration Degrees

Oscillation criteria for two-dimensional system of non-linear ordinary differential equations

Mean-Variance Analysis

Lecture 34 Bootstrap confidence intervals

Homework 8 Model Solution Section

Some new generalized topologies via hereditary classes. Key Words:hereditary generalized topological space, A κ(h,µ)-sets, κµ -topology.

Appendix to Technology Transfer and Spillovers in International Joint Ventures

CHAPTER 101 FOURIER SERIES FOR PERIODIC FUNCTIONS OF PERIOD

Oscillation Criteria for Nonlinear Damped Dynamic Equations on Time Scales

MINIMAL CLOSED SETS AND MAXIMAL CLOSED SETS

= e 6t. = t 1 = t. 5 t 8L 1[ 1 = 3L 1 [ 1. L 1 [ π. = 3 π. = L 1 3s = L. = 3L 1 s t. = 3 cos(5t) sin(5t).

Απόκριση σε Μοναδιαία Ωστική Δύναμη (Unit Impulse) Απόκριση σε Δυνάμεις Αυθαίρετα Μεταβαλλόμενες με το Χρόνο. Απόστολος Σ.

Lecture 12 Modulation and Sampling

Space-Time Symmetries

Econ 2110: Fall 2008 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8 questions or comments to Dan Fetter 1

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval

Math 248 Homework 1. Edward Burkard. Exercise 1. Prove the following Fourier Transforms where a > 0 and c R: f (x) = b. f(x c) = e.

THE SECOND ISOMORPHISM THEOREM ON ORDERED SET UNDER ANTIORDERS. Daniel A. Romano

Fourier Transform. Fourier Transform

Multi-dimensional Central Limit Theorem

Partial Differential Equations in Biology The boundary element method. March 26, 2013

Approximation of the Lerch zeta-function

EQUATIONS OF DEGREE 3 AND 4.

Pg The perimeter is P = 3x The area of a triangle is. where b is the base, h is the height. In our case b = x, then the area is

Transcript:

Managing Producion-Invenory Sysems wih Scarce Resources Online Supplemen Proof of Lemma 1: Consider he following dynamic program: where ḡ (x, z) = max { cy + E f (y, z, D)}, (7) x y min(x+u,z) f (y, z, d) = max { L(y l) + py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l)}, (8) l min(d,z) and ḡ (x, z) =, for z x, where L(x) = ( p + αc)x h(x) + b( x) +. Le Ḡ(y, z) = cy + E f (y, z, D) and F (y, z, l) = L(y l) + py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l). I can be shown by inducion ha xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) p c. Noe ha l F p αc + h α( x (y, z, l) = v 1(y l, z l) + z v 1(y l, z l)), if l y, p αc b α( x v 1(y l, z l) + z v 1(y l, z l)), if l > y. Clearly, when b p αc, l F (y, z, l) if l y; and l F (y, z, l) if l > y. This implies ha f (y, z, d) = F (min(y, d), z, d) for y z and ḡ (x, z) = max { cy + E F (min(y, D), z, D)}, x y min(x+u,z) = max x y min(x+u,z) {(p c)y + (p αc + h)e(y D)+ + αeḡ 1 ((y D) +, z min(y, d))}. Compare he above equaion wih Equaion (2), we have v (x, z) = ḡ (x, z) for all x, z and =,..., T, and V (x, z) = Ḡ(y, z) for all y, z and =,..., T, when b p αc. Therefore, we have x v (x, z) + z v (x, z) p c. To show ha V (y, z) saisfies properies (a), (b) and (c), we only need o show ha V (y, z) is L -convex, or equivalenly, Ḡ(y, z) is L -convex. In he following, we prove by inducion ha ḡ (x, z) and Ḡ(y, z) are boh L -convex for = 1,..., T. We have ḡ (x, z) = for z x. Clearly, ḡ (x, z) is L -convex. Suppose ḡ 1 (x, z) is L -convex. I can be easily verified ha L(x) is concave. By Lemma 1 of Zipkin (28), 1

ḡ 1 (y l, z l) is L -convex in (y, z, l) and L(y l) is L -convex in (y, l). Then, F (y, z, l) = L(y l) + py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l) is L -convex. By propery (b) of Lemma 2 of Huh and Janakiraman (21), we see ha f (y, z, d) = min { F (y, z, l)} is L -convex in (y, z) l min(d,z) for fixed d. Thus, Ḡ(y, z) = cy E f (y, z, D) is L -convex. Again, by propery (b) of Lemma 2 of Huh and Janakiraman (21), ḡ (x, z) = min x y min(x+u,z) { Ḡ(y, z)} is L -convex. This complees he inducion and he proof. Proof of Theorem 2: Le ȳ (z) = argmax V (y, z) and y (x, q ) = ȳ (x + q ). Since V (y, z) y z is concave in y, he opimal producion hreshold is given by y (x, q ) = argmax V (y, x + q ) = x y min(x +u,x +q ) Clearly, y (x, q ) depends only on he sum x + q. x, if x y (x, q ), y (x, q ), if x y (x, q ) x + u, x + u, if x + u y (x, q ). Since V (y, z) is L -convex and ȳ (z) = argmin{ V (y, z)}, by propery (c) of Lemma 2 of y z Huh and Janakiraman (21), we have z ȳ(z) 1. This proves properies (a) and (b). Proof of Proposiion 3: I can be shown by inducion ha z v (x, z, u) p c. Noe ha v (x, q, u) = v (x, x + q, u) + cx. Thus, q v (x, q, u) = z v (x, x + q, u) [, p c] and 2 q 2 v (x, q, u) = 2 z 2 v (x, x + q, u). This proves properies (a) and (b). (c) If we can show v (x, z, u) = v (x, z x, u) cx is supermodular in (z, u), hen we have 2 qu v (x, q, u) = 2 zu v (x, z, u) z=x+q. In he following, we prove by inducion ha v (x, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u), π (z, u) = v (z, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u), and x v (x, z, u) + z v (x, z, u) is nondecreasing in u. Clearly, his is rue for = since v (x, z, u) =. Now, suppose v 1 (x, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u), π 1 (z, u) is supermodular in (z, u), and x v 1(x, z, u) + z v 1(x, z, u) is nondecreasing in u. Then, i is easy o verify ha V (y, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u) and Π (z, u) = V (z, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u). Moreover, y V (y, z, u)+ z V (y, z, u) = L (y)+α y [ x v 1(y ξ, z ξ, u)+ z v 1(y ξ, z ξ, u)]φ(ξ)dξ, which is nonincreasing in u. Equivalenly, u V (ȳ + δ, z, u + δ) u V (ȳ, z, u) for δ. Similar o he proofs of Lemma 1 and Theorem 2, we can show ha he opimal producion hreshold y (x, q, u) is nonincreasing in u and u y (x, z, u) 1. Thus, for fixed x and z, here exis u 1 2

and u 2, wih u 1 u 2, such ha x + u, if u [, u 1 ], y (x, z, u) = ȳ (z, u), if u [u 1, u 2 ], x, if u [u 2, ). When u [, u 1 ], v (x, z, u) = V (x, z, u), which is supermodular in (z, u). When u [u 2, ), v (x, z, u) = V (x + u, z, u), which is supermodular in (z, u) since V (y, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u) and (y, z). When u [u 1, u 2 ], if ȳ (z, u) = z, hen v (x, z, u) = V (z, z, u), which is supermodular in (z, u). This also implies ha π (z, u) = v (z, z, u) = V (z, z, u) is supermodular in (z, u). If ȳ (z, u) < z, we have v (x, z, u) = V (y (z, u), z, u) and u v (x, z, u) = V u (ȳ (z, u), z, u). Thus, for δ, u v (x, z + δ, u) = u V (ȳ (z + δ, u), z + δ, u) u V (ȳ (z, u) + δ, z + δ, u) u V (ȳ, z, u) = u v (x, z, u). This implies ha v (x, z, u) is supermodular when u [u 1, u 2 ]. z, z v(x, z, u) in nondecreasing in u on [, u 1), (u 1, u 2 ), and (u 2, ). verified ha lim u u1 z v(x, z, u) lim u u 1 z v(x, z, u) and lim u u 2 z v(x, z, u) lim u u 2 Therefore, for fixed x and Moreover, i can be z v(x, z, u). Thus, z v(x, z, u) in nondecreasing in u for all u and v (x, u, z) in supermodular in (u, z). Similarly, we can show x v (x, z, u) + z v (x, z, u) is nondecreasing in u. This complees he inducion and he proof. Proof of Theorem 4: Le ˆV (y, z) = L(y) + Eˆv 1 (z y + (y D) + ). Similar o he proofs of Lemma 1 and Theorem 2, we can show ha ˆv (z) is concave, ˆV (y, z) is joinly concave and supermodular, and ŷ (z) 1. We can also show by inducion ha v (z) is coninuously differeniable, ˆv (z) p c, and ˆv () = p c. Nex, we show by inducion ha ŷ (z) saisfies he following properies: (a) if z y b, hen ŷ (z) = y b, (b) if z < y b, hen z ŷ (z) y b, (c) if z ˇy, hen ŷ (z) = z, and (d) ŷ (z) is nonincreasing in. For (a), we show by inducion ha when z y b, v (z) =. For =, v (z) =. Now, suppose ha when z ( 1)y b, v 1 (z) =. Then, when z yb, we have z ξ ( 1)y b for ξ y b. Thus, v 1 (z ξ) = for ξ yb and V (y, z) y = L (y b ) α ˆv 1(z y b )φ(ξ)dξ =. y=y b y b 3

This implies ha ŷ (z) = y b. Therefore, when z y b, y b v (z) = α ˆv 1(z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ α ˆv 1(z y b )φ(ξ)dξ =. y b This complees he inducion. Moreover, from he above analysis, we can see ha he fac v (z) = when z y b implies ha ŷ +1 (z) = y b. Therefore, (a) holds for = 1,..., T. Nex, we prove (c). Noe ha for z ˇy, we have V (y, z) y = L (z) α y=z z ˆv 1()φ(ξ)dξ = (1 α)p c ((1 α)p + h)φ(z). This implies ha ŷ (z) = z when z ˇy and V y (y, z) y=ŷ(z) = when z ˇy. For (b), firs noe ha for = 1,..., T, when z ˇy, we have V y y=ŷ(z) (y, z) =, i.e., L (ŷ (z)) α(1 Φ(ŷ (z)))ˆv 1 (z ŷ (z)) =. Therefore, for = 1,..., T, when z ˇy, ˆv (z) = α( ŷ(z) = L (ŷ (z)) + α ˆv 1(z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ + ŷ(z) ŷ (z) ˆv 1(z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ L (ŷ (z)) + αφ(ŷ (z))ˆv 1(z ŷ (z)) ˆv 1(z ŷ (z))φ(ξ)dξ) = L (ŷ (z)) + Φ(ŷ (z)) 1 Φ(ŷ (z)) L (ŷ (z)) 1 = 1 Φ(ŷ (z)) L (ŷ (z)). (9) Since v 1 (z), we have V (y, z) y = L (y b ) α y=y b y b ˆv 1(z y b )φ(ξ)dξ. This implies ha ŷ (z) y b. Nex we show ha ŷ (z) z when z < yb. I can be easily verified ha ŷ 1 (z) = min(z, y b ). Thus, ŷ 1 (z) z when z < y b. Now, suppose ha ŷ 1 (z) z < ( 1)y b. Then, in period, we have V y y= (y, z) z consider wo cases: 1 V y (y, z) y= z z ˇy and 1 z 1 when = L ( z ) α(1 Φ( z ))ˆv 1 ( 1 z). We z > ˇy. For he firs case, we have z 1 z ˇy. Thus, L ( z ) α(1 Φ(z ))(p l) = (1 α)p c ((1 α)p + h)φ(z ). This implies ha ŷ (z) z. For he second case, by (9), we have ˆv 1( 1 1 z) 1 Φ(ŷ 1 ( 1 z)) L (ŷ 1 ( 1 where θ(y) = L (y) 1 Φ(y) nonincreasing on [, y b ]. Therefore, V (y, z) y y= z z)) = θ(ŷ 1 ( 1 z)), = p c (p αc+h)φ(y) 1 Φ(y). I can be verified ha θ(y) is nonnegaive and = L ( z ) α(1 Φ(z ))ˆv 1( 1 z) 4

1 1 Φ( z )(θ(z ) αθ(ŷ 1( 1 1 z))) 1 Φ( z )(θ(z ) θ(ŷ 1( 1 z))), where he las inequaliy is due o he inducive assumpion ha ŷ 1 ( 1 z) 1 1 1 z = z. This implies ha ŷ (z) z. For (d), we show by inducion ha ŷ (z) ŷ +1 (z) and ˆv (z) ˆv +1 (z). We have ˆv (z) = and ˆv (z) for all. Thus, ˆv (z) ˆv 1 (z). Now, suppose ˆv 1 (z) ˆv (z). When z ˇy, we have ŷ (z) = ŷ +1 (z) = z and ˆv (z) ˆv +1(z) = α z (ˆv 1(z ξ) ˆv (z ξ))φ(ξ)dξ. When z > ˇy, we have V (y, z) y = L (ŷ +1 (z)) α(1 Φ( z y=ŷ+1 (z) ))ˆv 1(z ŷ +1 (z)) This implies ha ŷ (z) ŷ +1 (z). We also have ˆv (z) ˆv +1(z) = L (ŷ ) L (ŷ +1 ) + α( L (ŷ +1 (z)) α(1 Φ( z ))ˆv (z ŷ +1 (z)) =. ŷ ŷ+1 v 1(z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ ŷ (p αc + h)(φ(ŷ ) Φ(ŷ +1 )) + α v 1(z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ ŷ +1 ŷ (p αc + h)(φ(ŷ ) Φ(ŷ +1 )) + α (p c)φ(ξ)dξ ŷ +1 = ((1 α)c + h)(φ(ŷ ) Φ(ŷ +1 )), v (z ξ)φ(ξ)dξ) where ŷ = ŷ (z), ŷ +1 = ŷ +1 (z), and he las inequaliy is due o he fac ha ŷ (z) ŷ +1 (z). Las we show ha he opimal producion hresholds of he sysem wih only he allowance consrain are exacly he same as hose of he relaxed sysem and herefore saisfy properies (a), (b), (c) and (d) in Theorem 4. We only need o show ha v (x, z) = ˆv (z) for x ŷ (z), and V y (y, z) for y > ŷ (z). This hen implies ha ŷ (z), if x y (z), argmax V (y, z) = x y z x, if x y (z). In oher words, y (x, q ) = ȳ (x + q ) = ŷ (x + q ). When =, we have v (x, z) = ˆv (z) =. Now, suppose ha v 1 (x, z) = ˆv 1 (z) for x ŷ 1 (z), and y V 1 (y, z) for y > ŷ 1 (z). Then, when x ŷ (z), since ŷ (z) 1 and ŷ 1 (z) ŷ (z), we have ŷ (z) ξ ŷ (z ξ) ŷ 1 (z ξ) for ξ ŷ (z). This implies ha (ŷ (z) D) + ŷ 1 (z y + (y D) + ). Thus, v 1 ((ŷ (z) D) +, z y + (y D) + ) = ˆv 1 (z y + (y D) + ) and ˆV (ŷ (z), z) = V (ŷ (z), z). As a consequence, ˆv (z) = ˆV (ŷ (z), z) = 5

V (ŷ (z), z) v (x, z) for x ŷ (z). Clearly, v (x, z) ˆv (z). Therefore, v (x, z) = ˆv (z) for x ŷ (z). Similarly, we can show ha ˆV (y, z) = V (y, z) for y ŷ (z). We can also prove by inducion ha V (y, z) is coninuously differeniable. Since V (y, z) is concave in y, hen for y > ŷ 1 (z), we have This complees he inducion and he proof. y V (y, z) y V (ŷ (z), z) = V (ȳ (z), z) =. Proof of Theorem 5: The proof is similar o he proofs of Lemma 8.5 and Theorem 8.4 in Poreus (22). Proof of Proposiion 6: Similar o he proof of Lemma 1, we can show ha v (x, z, u) is joinly concave in (x, z, u). Therefore, v (x, q, u) = v (x, x + q, u) is joinly concave in (q, u). This implies ha F T (c q, c u, x, q, u) = c q q c u u + v T (x, q, u) is joinly concave in (q, u). Proof of Proposiion 7: (a) Noe ha 2 F T 2 F T u 2 u T c q + 2 F T uc q =. Since 2 F T qc q 1 2 F T A, where A = 2 F T 2 F T u 2 q 2 u 2 2 F T u 2 qt c u q 2 q T c q = 1 and 2 F T uc q. Moreover, 2 F T qu = 2 v T qu. Therefore, q T c q and u T c u. (b) By Envelope Theorem, + 2 F T u T qu c q + 2 F T qc q =, we have q T c q = and 2 F T qt qu c q + = 1 2 F T A qu and q T c q = ( 2 F T qu )2. Since F T is joinly concave in (q, u), A and and u T c q c q F T (c q, c u, x) = q T (c q, c u, x) and. Similarly, we have c u F T (c q, c u, x) = u T (c q, c u, x). Moreover, F T (c q, c u, x, q, u) is convex in (c q, c u ). Since convexiy is preserved under maximizaion, F T (c q, c u, x) is convex in (c q, c u ). (c) When c u =, he sysem can be viewed as one wih only he allowance consrain. Thus, he second sage problem can be formulaed by opimaliy equaion (3), and he firs sage problem can be formulaed as max { c qq + v T (q)}. Le F (c q, q) = c q q + v T (q) and q le K be he smalles q such ha v T (q) =. Then for q < K, v T (q) >, and for q K, v T (q) =. This implies ha q T (,, ) = K. Noe ha v T (z) is wice differeniable. Thus we have v T (K) =. As a consequence, q T (c q,, ) c q = cq= Proof of Proposiion 8: Since c u 2 qc q F (cq, qt (c q,, )) 2 F (c q 2 q, qt (c q,, )) 1 = cq= v T (q T (c q,, )) =. cq= =, he sysem can be viewed as one wih only he allowance consrain. Le Q (x, q) denoe he expeced cumulaive amoun produced, under he opimal policy, from period o he end of he planning horizon, wih saring invenory level x and remaining allowance q. Then, u T (w, x) = Q T (x,c T (w,x)) c T (w,x). Noe ha Q (x, q), for = T,..., 1, 6

can be compued recursively as EQ 1 ((x D) +, q), Q (x, q) = y (x, q) x + EQ 1 ((y (x, q) D) +, x + c y (x, c)), if x y (x, c), oherwise, and Q (x, q) =. We can hen show by inducion ha, for 1 T, v (z) < when z < y b, and v (z) = when z y b. This implies ha q T (,, x) = (T yb x) +. We can also show by inducion ha q Q (x, q) = when x + q y b. As a consequence, η T (c q,, ) c q = q T (,, ) q Q (, q T (,, )) c q qt (,, ) Q (, q T (,, )) c q qt (,, ) cq= (qt (,, ))2 = T yb q Q (, T y b ) Q (, T y b ) (T y b ) 2 c q q T (,, ) =. Proof of Theorem 9: Le ḡ (x, z) = v(x, z x) cx, f (y, z, d) = f (y, z y, d), and L(x) = ( p + αc)x h(x) + b( x) +. Then we can rewrie he opimaliy equaions in (5) and (6) as (7) and (8). In he proof of Lemma 1, we show ha xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) p c and F (y, z, l) = L(y l) + py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l) is concave in l. Le l (y, z) = argmax { L(y l) + l z py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l)}. When l y, we have l F (y, z, l) = p αc + h α( xḡ 1(y l, z l) + z ḡ 1(y l, z l)). This implies ha l (y, z) = argmax{( p + αc)(y l) b(l y) + py + αḡ 1 (y l, z l)}. Le y l z w (q) = argmax{(p αc b)w+αḡ 1 ( w, q w)}. Then l (y, z) = y+w (z y). Given invenory w q level y, remaining allowance q 1, and realized demand d, he opimal amoun of demand o fulfill equals min(d, y +w (q 1 )). By propery (c) of Lemma 2 of Huh and Janakiraman (21), we have d dq w (q) 1. For (c), noe ha w (q) = argmax{(p αc b)w + αḡ 1 ( w, q w)}. If we can show w q xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) xḡ 1(x, z) + z ḡ 1(x, z), hen we have w (q) w+1 (q). Nex we show by inducion ha xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) xḡ+1(x, z) + z ḡ+1(x, z) and z ḡ(x, z) z ḡ+1(x, z). Clearly, xḡ1(x, z)+ z ḡ1(x, z) = xḡ(x, z)+ z ḡ(x, z) and z ḡ1(x, z) = z ḡ(x, z). Now, suppose xḡ 1(x, z)+ z ḡ 1(x, z) xḡ(x, z)+ z ḡ(x, z) and z ḡ 1(x, z) z ḡ(x, z). Then, we have w (q) w+1 (q). By he srucure of he opimal fulfillmen policy, Ḡ (y, z) = cy + + + y y+w y [( p + αc)(y ξ) h(y ξ) + py + αḡ 1 (y ξ, z ξ)]φ(ξ)dξ y+w [( p + αc)(y ξ) b(ξ y) + py + αḡ 1 (y ξ, z ξ)]φ(ξ)dξ [( p + αc)( w ) bw + py + αḡ 1 ( w, z y w )]φ(ξ)dξ, 7

where w = w (z y). Hence, y Ḡ(y, z) + z Ḡ(y, z) =p c (h + b)φ(y) (p αc b)φ(y + w ) + α y+w [ x v 1(y ξ, z ξ) + z v 1(y ξ, z ξ)]φ(ξ)dξ. By he definiion of w, x v 1(y w, z w) + z v 1(y w, z w) (p αc b) for any w [, w ] and x v 1(y w, z w) + z v 1(y w, z w) (p αc b) for any w [w, z]. This implies ha y Ḡ(y, z) + z Ḡ(y, z) p c (h + b)φ(y) (p αc b)φ(y + w+1) + α y+w +1 [ x v 1(y ξ, z ξ) + z v 1(y ξ, z ξ)]φ(ξ)dξ = p c (h + b)φ(y) (p αc b)φ(y + w +1) + α y+w +1 [ x v (y ξ, z ξ) + z v (y ξ, z ξ)]φ(ξ)dξ = y Ḡ+1(y, z) + z Ḡ+1(y, z). Similarly, we can show ha z Ḡ(y, z) z Ḡ+1(y, z). I can be verified ha, for n = 1,..., T, xḡn(x, z) + z ḡn(x, z) = ( y Ḡn(y, z) + z Ḡn(y, z)) y=yn(x,z), where y n (x, z) is he opimal order-up-o level in period n. Le ȳ (z) = argmax{ cy + y z E f (y, z, D)}. If ȳ (z) ȳ +1 (z), hen y (x, z) y +1 (x, z) and xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) ( y Ḡ(y, z) + z Ḡ(y, z)) y=y+1 (x,z) ( y Ḡ+1(y, z) + z Ḡ+1(y, z)) = xḡ+1(x, z) + z ḡ+1(x, z), where he firs inequaliy is due o he L -convexiy of Ḡ(y, z). y=y+1 (x,z) If ȳ (z) < ȳ +1 (z), hen y (x, z) y +1 (x, z). I can be verified ha xḡ(x, z) xḡ+1(x, z). Moreover, z ḡ(x, z) = z Ḡ(y, z) y=y(x,z) z Ḡ(y, z) y=y+1 (x,z) z Ḡ+1(y, z)) = y=y+1 (x,z) z ḡ+1(x, z), where he firs inequaliy is due o he supermodulariy of Ḡ (y, z). Therefore, xḡ(x, z) + z ḡ(x, z) xḡ+1(x, z) + z ḡ+1(x, z). Similarly, we can show z ḡ(x, z) z ḡ+1(x, z). This complees he inducion and he proof. Proof of Proposiion 1: Noe ha w (q) = argmax{( p + αc b)w + αḡ 1 ( w, q w). w q When p αc b, we have p αc b α( xḡ 1( w, q w)+ z ḡ 1( w, q w)) p αc b. This implies ha w (q) =. When (1 αc)p b, we have p αc b α( xḡ 1( w, q w) + 8

z ḡ 1( w, q w)) p αc b α(p c). This implies ha w (q) = q. (a) and (b) are proved. For (c), noe ha given x and q, i is opimal o back order a mos w (x + q y (x, q )) unis of demand, where y (x, q ) is defined in he proof of Theorem 2. Since w (q) is nondecreasing in q and x + q y (x, q) is nondecreasing in q, w (x + q y (x, q )) is nondecreasing in q. Clearly, w (x + q y (x, q )) > when q is sufficienly large. Le q (x ) be he larges q such ha w (x + q y (x, q )) =. Then w (x + q y (x, q )) = when q q (x ) and w (x + q y (x, q )) > when q > q (x ). References Huh WT, Janakiraman G (21). On he Opimal Policy Srucure in Serial Invenory Sysems wih Los Sales. Operaions Research. 58(2):486-491. Poreus E (22). Foundaions of Sochasic Invenory Theory. (Sanford Universiy Press, Redwood Ciy, CA) Zipkin P (28). On he Srucure of Los-Sales Invenory Models. Operaions Research. 56(4):937-944. 9