Mathematical model of a stock market

Μέγεθος: px
Εμφάνιση ξεκινά από τη σελίδα:

Download "Mathematical model of a stock market"

Transcript

1 Condensed Matter Physics, 2000, Vol. 3, No. 3(23), pp Mathematical model of a stock market N.S.Gonchar Bogolubov Institute for Theoretical Physics of the National Academy of Sciences of Ukraine, 4 b Metrolohichna Str., Kyiv, Ukraine Received May 30, 2000 In this paper we construct a mathematical model of securities market. The results obtained are a good basis for an analysis of any stock market. Key words: random process, effective stock market, option pricing PACS: s, j Dedicated to prominent scientist Igor Yukhnovsky, initiator of my perspective research on economy.. Introduction The aim of this paper is to propose a wide class of random processes to describe the evolution of a risk active price and to construct a mathematical theory of option pricing. For this purpose, a general mathematical model of evolution of a risk active price is proposed on a probability space constructed. On the probability space, an evolution of a risk active price is described by a random process with jumps that can have both finite and infinite number of jumps. We introduce a new notion of non-singular martingale and prove an integral representation for a wide class of local martingale by a path integral. This theorem is the basic result of the paper that permits us to introduce the important notion of an effective stock market. For an effective stock market the mathematical theory of European type options is constructed. As a result, the new formulas for option pricing, the capital investor and self-financing strategy corresponding to the minimal hedge are obtained. 2. Some auxiliary results Hereafter we will use two elementary lemmas the proof of which is omitted. Lemma. For any on the right continuous functions ϕ(x) and ψ(x), that have the c N.S.Gonchar 46

2 N.S.Gonchar bounded variation on [a, b), the following formula ϕ(d)ψ(d) ϕ(c)ψ(c) = ϕ (y)dψ(y)+ ψ(y)dϕ(y), (c,d] [a,b) () (c,d] (c,d] is valid, F (u) = lim v u F(v). By dϕ(y) and dψ(y) we denoted the charges, generated by functions ϕ(y) and ψ(y) correspondingly, ϕ (x) = lim y x ϕ(y). Lemma 2. The Radon-Nicodym derivative of the measure dg(y), generated by the function g(y) = ( F(y)), with respect to the measure df(y), where F(y) is on the right continuous and monotonouosly non-decreasing on [a, b) function and such that F(a) = 0, F(x) <,x [a,b),lim x b F(x) = is given by the formula dg(y) df(y) = ( F(y))( F (y)). Lemma 3. For on the right continuous and monotoneously non-decreasing function α(x) such that α(x) <, x [a,b), α(a) = 0, lim x b α(x) =, the representation α(x) = df(y) F (y) is valid for a certain F(x), that is on the right continuous and monotonously nondecreasingfunction, satisfying conditions:f(x) <, x [a,b),limf(x) =,F(a) = x b 0, if and only if there exists a positive, on the right continuous and monotoneously non-decreasing solution of equation φ(x) = φ(y)dα(y) + (3) such that φ(a) = 0, φ(x) <,x [a,b). The function F(x) is given by the formula (2) F(x) = φ(x). (4) φ(x) Proof.The necessity.bydefinitionweputf (y) = lim x y F(x).Iftherepresentation (2) holds, then the following equality 462 dα(y) F(y) = df(y) ( F(y))( F (y)) = F(x)

3 Mathematical model of a stock market is valid. Therefore, the function φ(x) = F(x) is a positive, on the right continuous and monotonously non-decreasing solution of equation (3). The sufficiency. If there exists a solution to (3), satisfying conditions of lemma 3, then the function (4) satisfies equation dα(y) F(y) + = F(x). But The latter means that or df(y) ( F(y))( F (y)) + = F(x). dα(y) F(y) = dα(y) = From the latter equality it follows that α(x) = df(y) ( F(y))( F (y)), df(y) ( F (y)). df(y) ( F (y)). Lemma 3 is proved. Let us give the necessary and sufficient conditions for the existence of a solution to equation (3) Lemma 4. Nonnegative solution to the equation (3) exists if and only if the series φ(x) = + converges for all x [a,b). n= dα(t ) [a,t ] dα(t 2 )... [a,t n ] dα(t n ) (5) Proof. The necessity. If there exists a non-negative solution to (3), then this solution is the solution to the equation φ(x) = + k n= dα(t ) [a,t ] dα(t 2 )... [a,t n ] dα(t n ) 463

4 N.S.Gonchar + dα(t ) dα(t 2 )... dα(t k ) φ(t k+ )dα(t k+ ). [a,t ] [a,t k ] From the latter equality there follows the inequality + k n= dα(t ) [a,t ] dα(t 2 )... [a,t k ] [a,t n ] dα(t n ) φ(x). Arbitrariness of k, positiveness of every term of the series means the convergence of (5). The proof of sufficiency follows from the fact that if the series (5) converges then this series is evidently a solution to the equation (3). The lemma 4 is proved. Corollary. If α(x) is a continuous and monotonously non-decreasing function, α(x) <, x [a,b), limα(x) =, α(a) = 0, then the equation (3) has the x b solution φ(x) = e α(x). Corollary 2. If γ(x) is some measurable function on [a, b), which satisfies the inequality γ(y)dα(y)+ γ(x), x [a,b), then there exists a solution to equation (3). Lemma 5. The solution to the equation (3) exists if jumps of monotonously nondecreasing and on the right continuous function α(x) is such that α(s). It has the following form φ(x) = e α(x) e α(s) ( α(s)). {s x} If 0 α(s) <, s [a,b), then this solution is non-negative, on the right continuous and monotonously non-decreasing function, α(s) = α(s) α (s). Proof. First of all the product converges, because the estimate {s x} {s x} e α(s) ( α(s)) α(s) α(x) <, x < b is valid. Let us verify that φ(x) is a solution to (3) in the case when all jump points of α(x) are isolated points. It is sufficient to prove that if φ(x) is the solution to (3) on a certain interval [a,x 0 ] and we prove that φ(x) is the solution to (3) on the interval (x 0,x], x > x 0 then it will mean that φ(x) is the solution to (3) on the interval. We assume that the points x i,i =,2,... are the jump points of the function α(x). To verify that φ(x) is the solution to the equation (3) let us assume that we 464

5 Mathematical model of a stock market have already proved that on the interval [a,x i ), where x i is the jump point of the function α(x), φ(x) is the solution to equation (3), that is, φ(y)dα(y) = φ (x i ) = e α e (x) α(s) ( α(s)). [a,x i ) {s<x i } Let x be any point that satisfies the condition x i < x < x i+. Since + φ(y)dα(y) = + φ(y)dα(y) + φ(y)dα(y) + φ(y)dα(y) +[e α(x) e α(x i) ] [a,x i ) [x i ] = φ (x i ) +e α(x i) α(x i ) {s x i } {s x i } e α(s) ( α(s)) + = eα(x) (x i,x] e α(s) ( α(s)) {s x} e α(s) ( α(s)) = φ(x). To completethe proof of thelemmaitisnecessary to note that onthe interval[a,x ) the solution to (3) is the function e α(x). Let us prove lemma 5 in a general case. If α(x) satisfies the conditions to lemma 5, then α(x) = α c (x)+ α(s), {s x} where α c (x) is a continuous function on [a,b). Let us introduce the notation where φ m (x) = e αm(x) α m (x) = α c (x)+ {s x} e αm(s) ( α m (s)), {s x, α(s) m } α(s). In the latter sum the summation comes over all jumps of α(x), where the jumps of α(x) are greater than m. It is evident that on any interval the set of such points is finite. Therefore φ m (x) satisfies the equation φ m (x) = φ m (y)dα m (y)+. (6) Let d < b, then {s d, α(s) m } sup φ(x) φ m (x) sup x [a,d] ( α(s)) e αc(x) x [a,d] {s d, α(s) m } {s d} ( α(s)) ( α(s)) 465

6 Moreover, sup x [a,d] var [α(x) α m(x)] x [a,d] e αc(x) {s d, α(s)<m } {s d} α(s) ( α(s)) {s d, α(s)<m } 0, m. α(s) 0, m, N.S.Gonchar where var x [a,d] g(x) means a full variation of the function g(x). From these inequalities we have [φ m (y) φ(y)]dα m (y) sup φ m (x) φ(x) var α(x) 0, m, x [a,d] x [a,d] φ(y)d[α m (y) α(y)] sup φ(x) var [α m (y) α(y)] 0,m. x [a,d] x [a,d] From the equality φ m (x) = [φ m (y) φ(y)]dα m (y)+ φ(y)d[α m (y) α(y)]+ φ(y)dα(y) + and from the preceding inequalities there follows the proof of the lemma 5. Theorem. Let ψ(y) be an on the right continuous function of bounded variation on any interval, x [a,b), f(y) be a measurable mapping with respect to the Borel σ-algebra on [a,b) and bounded function on, x [a,b). If, moreover, α(x) = dψ(y) <, x [a,b) (7) ψ(y) f(y) is monotonously non-decreasing and on the right continuous function on [a, b) and such that ) 0 α(x) <, α(x) = α(x) α (x), x [a,b), 2) limα(x) =, α(a) = 0, x b 3) limψ(x)e α(x) = 0, x b 4) b a f(x) e α (x) dα(x) <, then for the function ψ(x) the following representation ψ(x) = f(x)df(x) ( F(x)) is valid for a certain monotonously non-decreasing and on the right continuous function F(x), such that F(a) = 0, F(x) <, x [a,b), lim x b F(x) =. 466 (x,b)

7 Mathematical model of a stock market Proof. Let F(x) be the function, which is constructed in the lemma 3. Let us consider the product [ F(x)]ψ(x). Then for x < d < b [ F(x)]ψ(x)+[ F(d)]ψ(d) = [ F (y)]dψ(y) ψ(y)df(y). (x,d] (x,d] From the lemma 3 df(y) dψ(y) = [ψ(y) f(y)] ( F (y)). Therefore, [ F(x)]ψ(x)+[ F(d)]ψ(d) = f(y)df(y). (8) (x,d] Since = [ F(d)]ψ(d) e α(d) ψ(d) 0, d b, f(y)df(y) f(y) df(y)= (x,d] (x,d] f(y) [ F (y)]dα(y) f(y) e α (y) dα(y) <, (x,d] (x,b) then, taking the limit in the equality (8), we obtain [ F(x)]ψ(x) = f(y)df(y). The theorem is proved. Theorem 2. Let g(u) be a measurable function with respect to B([a,b)) and such that g(y) df(y)<, (d,b) [a,b) (x,b) then the following formula g(y)df(y) ( F(d)) ( F(c)) is valid. = (c,d] ( F(u)) (u,b) (c,b) g(y)df(y) = g(y)df(y) g(u) df(u), (c,d] [a,b) (9) F (u) 467

8 N.S.Gonchar Proof. If we choose ϕ(x) = ( F(x)), ψ(x) = (x,b) g(u)df(u) and use lemmas and 2 we obtain the proof of the theorem Probability space Hereafter we construct a probability space, in which the securities market evolution will be considered. Let α = {a α i } + be a sequence from [a,b) R+, a < b, that satisfies conditions: a α i < a α i+, i =,, [a α i,a α i+) = [a,b), a α = a, a α + = b. Therefore, the set of intervals {[a α i,aα i+ ), i =,} forms a decomposition of interval [a,b) R+. The number may be both finite and infinite. Further on, we consider the family of probability spaces Ω i = [a,b), i =,. On every probabilityspace Ω i a σ-algebraofevents Fi 0 isgiven. Bydefinitiontheσ-algebraFi 0 is the set of subsets of Ω i = [a,b), that is generated by intervals (c,d) [a α i,a α i+). Let us determine the flow of the σ-algebras F 0,t i, t [a,b), F 0,t i Fi 0, by the formula F 0,t i = {,[a,b)}, a t a α i, B([a α i,t]), aα i < t < a α i+, t [a α i,aα i+ ) B([a α i,t]) = F 0 i, a α i+ t b, where we denoted by B([a α i,t]) the σ-algebra of subsets of [a,b) generated by the subsets of (c,d) [a α i,t] and B([a α i,t]) denotes the σ-algebra, that is the t [a α i,aα i+ ) union of the σ-algebras B([a α i,t]). Let {Ω α,fα 0 } be the direct product of measurable spaces {Ω i,fi 0 },i =,, and F0,α t = be the flow of the σ-algebras on the measurable space {Ω α,fα 0 }, that is the direct product of the σ-algebras F0,t i, where Ω α = Ω i,fα 0 =. Let us determine a certain measurable space Fi 0 {Ω,F 0 }. Denote by X a set of sequences α = {a α i } + from [a, b) that generate decomposition of [a,b). Let Ω = Ω α be the direct sum of the probability spaces α X Ω α = {α,ω α }. Elements of Ω α are the pairs {α,ω α }, where ω α Ω α Let us denote by F α 0 the σ-algebra of events of the kind Āα = {α,a α }, where A α Fα 0, {α,a α} = = {{α,ω α }, ω α A α }. Analogously, F0,α t is the flow of the σ-algebras from Ω α of the sets of the kind {α,a α }, where A α F 0,α t. It is evident that Ω α Ω β =,α β. 468 F 0,t i

9 Mathematical model of a stock market Let Σ be the σ-algebra of all subsets of X. Introduce a σ-algebra F 0 and the flow of the σ-algebras F 0 t in Ω. We assume that the σ-algebra F 0 in Ω is the set of the subsets of the kind C Y = α Y B α, Y Σ, B α F 0 α. This follows from the following inclusions C Yi = B α F 0, C Yi = B α F 0, C Y \C Y2 = B α F 0. α Y \Y 2 α Y i α Y i By analogy with the construction of the σ-algebra F 0, the flow of the σ-algebra F 0 t F0 is the set of the subsets of the type C Y = α Y B α, Y Σ, B α F 0,α t. Further on we deal with the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } and the flow of the σ- algebras Ft 0 F 0 on it. Hereafter we construct the probability space {Ω,F 0,P}. Define a probability measure P α on the measurable space {Ω α,fα 0 }. For this purpose on every measurable space {Ω i,fi 0 } we determine the familyof distribution functions Fi α(ωα i {ω, that at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i = i Ω s is on the right continuous and non-decreasing function of the variable ωi α [a,b), F α i (ωα i {ω = s= 0, a ω α i a α i, {ω α} i Ω i, φ α i (ω α i {ω α } i ), a α i < ω α i < a α i+, {ω α } i Ω i,, a α i+ ωα i < b, {ω α } i Ω i, where {ω α } i = {ω α,...,ωα i }, ω α = {ω α,...,ωα }. The function φ α i (ωα i {ω satisfies the conditions: 0 φ α i (ωα i {ω <, it is on the right continuous and non-decreasing function of the variable ωi α on [a α i,aα i+ ) at every fixed {ω α} i Ω i, moreover, it is a measurable function from the measurable space {Ω i, F i 0 } to the measurable space {[0,],B([0,])} at every fixed ωi α, where B([0,]) is the Borel σ-algebra on [0,], F0 i = i Fs. 0 Denote by Fi α(dωα i {ω the measure constructed by the distribution function Fi α (ωi α {ω α } i ) onthe σ-algebrafi 0 at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i. It isevident that Fi α(dωα i {ω is concentrated on the subset [a α i,aα i+ ) Ω i. Let us determine a measure on the probability space {Ω α,fα}, 0 having determined it on the set of the type A... A, A i Fi 0 by the formula =... A P α (A... A ) = A F α (dωα )Fα 2 (dωα 2 {ω α} )... F α (dωα {ω α} ). s= 469

10 N.S.Gonchar The function of the sets so defined can be extended to a certain measure P α on Fα 0 due to Ionescu and Tulcha theorem []. We put by definition that on the σ-algebra F α 0 the probability measure P α is given by the formula P α (Āα) = P α (A α ). Further on we consider both the probability spaces {Ω α,fα 0,P α} and the probability spaces { Ω α, F α, 0 P α }, that are isomorphic, and the flows of the σ-algebras F 0,α t Fα 0 and F 0,α t F α 0 onthespacesω α and Ω α correspondingly.ifµ(y)isaprobabilitymeasure on Σ, we put that on the σ-algebra F 0 the probability measure P is given by the formula P(C Y ) = P α (B α )dµ(α), C Y = B α, Y Σ, B α F α. 0 α Y Y The latter integral exists, because P α (B α ) is a measurable mapping from the measurablespace {X,Σ} to the measurablespace {R,B(R )}, where B(R ) is the Borel σ-algebra on R. Further on we consider the probability space {Ω,F 0,P} and the flow of the σ-algebras F 0 t F 0 on it, the probability space {Ω,F,P} and the flow of the σ- algebras F t F, where F and F t are the completion of F 0 and F 0 t correspondingly with respect to the measure P. Then we use the same notation P for the extension of a measure P from the σ-algebra F 0 onto the σ-algebra F, where the σ-algebra F is the completion of the σ-algebra F 0 by the sets of zero measure with respect to the measure P given on the σ-algebra F Random processes on the probability space Definition. A consistent with the flow of the σ-algebras F 0 t measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) from the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } to the measurable space {R,B(R )} belongs to a certain class K if for ζ t ({α,ω α }) the representation ζ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ζ i,α t ({ω α } i ), ζ i,α t ({ω α } i ) = f α i ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ω α i )+ψα i ({ω α} i,t)χ (t, a α i+ )(ω α i ), t [a α i,a α i+) (0) is valid, where f α i ({ω α} i ) is a measurable mapping from the measurable space {Ω i, F 0 i } to the measurable space {R,B(R )} at every fixed α X 0, i =,, ψ α i ({ω α} i,t) is a measurable mapping from the measurable space {Ω i, F 0 i } to the measurable space {R,B(R )} at every fixed t [a α i,aα i+ ), α X0, i = 2,. Further we deal with the space X 0 that consists of sequences α = {a α i }+ not having limiting points on the interval, x < b, Σ is the σ-algebra of all subsets of X 0. Hereinafter χ D (t) denotes the indicator function of the set D from [a,b). 470

11 Mathematical model of a stock market Definition 2. By K 0 we denote the subclass of the class K of measurable mappings, satisfying conditions: ) ψi α({ω α} i,t) is an on the right continuous function of bounded variation of the variable t on any interval [a α i,τ],τ [aα i,aα i+ ) at every fixed {ω α} i Ω i, i = =,. 2) fi α({ω α} i ) is a measurable and bounded mapping from the measurable space {Ω i, F i 0 } to the measurable space {R,B(R )}. 3) The function γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) = [a α i, t] ψi α ({ω α } i,dτ) [ψi α({ω α} i,τ) fi α({ω, i =,, () α} i,τ)] where fi α ({ω α } i,τ) = fi α ({ω α } i ) ωi α = τ, is monotonously non-decreasing and on the right continuous function of the variable t on the interval [a α i,aα i+ ) at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i, α X 0, satisfying conditions: a) γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) <, {ω α } i Ω i, t [a α i,a α i+), γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) = γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) γ i,α ({ω α } i,t ), γ i,α ({ω α } i,t ) = limγ i,α ({ω α } i,s). s t b) lim γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) =, γ i,α ({ω α } i,a α t a α i ) = 0, {ω α } i Ω i,α X 0. i+ c) lim ψ t a α i α ({ω α } i,t)exp{ γ i,α ({ω α } i,t)} = 0, i+ d) fi α({ω α} i,t) exp{ γ i,α ({ω α } i,t )}γ i,α ({ω α } i,dt) <, [a α i, aα i+ ) {ω α } i Ω i,α X 0. We denoted by γ i,α ({ω α } i,dt) the measure on B([a α i,aα i+ )), generated by the monotonously non-decreasing and on the right continuous function γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) of the variable t at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i, B([a α i,a α i+)) is the Borel σ-algebra on the interval [a α i,aα i+ ). Lemma 6. Any on the right continuous and uniformly integrable martingale on the probability space {Ω,F,P} with respect to the flow F t is given by the formula where m i,α M t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)m i,α t ({ω α } i ), (2) t ({ω α } i ) = fi α ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α )+ψα i ({ω α} i,t)χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), fi α ({ω α} i ) =... g α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ) Ω i+ Ω ψ α i ({ω α } i,t) = Fi+(dω α i+ {ω α α } i )... F(dω α {ω α α } ), Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ), (t, a α i+ ) i =,, α X 0, (3) 47

12 N.S.Gonchar g α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ) is a measurable and integrable function on the probability space {Ω,F,P}, that is, X 0 M α g({α,ω α }) dµ(α) <. Proof. Further on, for the mapping g α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ) we use one more notation g({α,ω α })=g α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ), where {ω α } i ={ω α,...,ω α i }, {ω α } [i,] = {ω α i+,...,ωα }, ω α = {ω α,...,ωα } = {{ω α} i,{ω α } [i,] }. Taking into account the σ-algebra Σ from X 0 consists of all subsets of X 0 to prove the lemma 6, it is sufficient to calculate the conditional expectation M{g({β,ω β }) F t } β=α = M α {g({α,ω α }) F 0,α t }, where g({α,ω α }) is a measurable and integrable function on the probability space 0,α {Ω,F,P}, M α {g({α,ω α }) F t } is the conditional expectation with respect to the 0,α flow of the σ-algebras F t F α 0 on the probability space { Ω α, F α, 0 P α }. Suppose that t [a α i,aα i+ ). From this it follows that ϕ t i ({ω α}) = M α {g({α,ω α }) F 0,α t } 0,α is the measurable mapping from { Ω α, F t, P α } to {R,B(R 0,α )}, where F t = i Fs 0 F0,t i O s, O s = {,[a,b)}, s = i+,. Due to the structure s= s=i+ 0,α F t of the σ-algebra it follows that ϕ t i ({ω α}) depends only on variables {ω α } i and ϕ t i({ω α }) is a measurablemappingfrom{ω i, i Fs F 0 0,t i } to {R,B(R )}. Granting this notation we have s= ϕ t i ({ω α}) = Q t i ({ω α} i ) = ϕ α i ({ω α } i,t)χ [a α i, t](ω α i )+ψ α i ({ω α } i,t)χ (t, a α i+ )(ω α i ). (4) Really, Q t i({ω α } i ) = Q t i({ω α } i )χ [a α i, t](ω α i )+Q t i({ω α } i )χ (t, a α i+ )(ω α i ). Because of the fact that Q t i({ω α } i )χ [a α i,t](ωi α ) is a measurable mapping from {Ω i, i Fs 0 F0,t i } to {R,B(R )} it follows that Q t i ({ω α} i )χ (t,a α i+ )(ωi α ) is also the s= measurable mapping. But this is possible, when Q t i ({ω α} i ) does not depend on the variable ωi α (t,b), because the only measurable sets i B s A i belong to the σ-algebra i 472 Putting s= F 0 s F0,t i, when ω α i (t,b), where B s F 0 s, A i = [a,a α i ) (t,b). s= Q t i ({ω α} i ) = ϕ α i ({ω α} i,t), {ω α } i Ω i [a α i,t], Q t i({ω α } i ) = ψ α i ({ω α } i,t), {ω α } i Ω i {[a,a α i ) (t,b)},

13 Mathematical model of a stock market we prove the representation (4). Taking into account the definition of the conditional expectation we have... Q t i ({ω α} i )F α (dωα )... Fα i (dωα i {ω = B B i A = g({α,ω α })F α (dωα )... Fα (dωα {ω α} ), B A Ω i+ Ω B i B s Ω s, s =,i, A F 0,t i. (5) Let us introduce the measurable mapping fi α ({ω α} i ) =... Ω i+ Ω g α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ) F α i+ (dωα i+ {ω α} i )... F α (dωα {ω α} ) from the measurable space {Ω i, F i 0} to the measurable space {R,B(R )}. It is evident that... fi α ({ω α} i ) F α (dωα )... Fα i (dωα i {ω M α g({α,ω α }) <. Ω Ω i From this and (5) it follows that ψ α i ({ω α} i,t) = ϕ α i ({ω α} i,t) = fi α ({ω α} i ), Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω, (t, a α i+ ) i =,, α X 0. It is evident that between fi α({ω α} i ) there exists the following relations fi α ({ω α} i ) = fi+ α ({ω α} i+)fi+ α (dωα i+ {ω α} i ), i =,, α X 0. Ω i+ The proof of the lemma 6 is completed. Lemma 7. Let a measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) on the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } belong to the subclass K 0, for every fixed α X 0, i =,, ψ α i ({ω α } i,a α i ) = f α i ({ω α } i ), {ω α } i Ω i and there exists a constant A < such that (a)dµ(α) A X 0 ψ α 473

14 N.S.Gonchar for a certain probability measure µ on Σ. If f α i ({ω α} i ) 0, then on the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } there exist a measure P on the σ-algebra F 0 and a modification ζ t ({α,ω α }) of the measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }), such that ζ t ({α,ω α }) is a local martingale on the probability space {Ω,F,P} with respect to the flow of the σ-algebra F t, where the σ-algebras F and F t are the completion of the σ-algebras F 0 and F 0 t correspondingly with respect to the measure P. Proof. The proof of the lemma 7 follows from the theorem. Really, all conditions of the theorem are valid. Therefore, there exists a family of distribution functions Fi α(ωα i {ω, i =,, α X 0,{ω α } i Ω i,withtheproperties,described at the introduction of the probability space {Ω,F,P}, that for ψi α ({ω α } i,t) the following representation ψi α ({ω α } i,t) = Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ), (t, a α i+ ) i =,, α X 0, is valid. Let us consider the measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t) ζ i,α t ({ω α } i ), ζ i,α t ({ω α } i }) = fi α ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) on the probability space {Ω,F,P} consistent with the flow of the σ-algebras F t, where the σ-algebras F and F t are the completion of the σ-algebras F 0 and Ft 0 correspondingly with respect to the measure P, generated by the family of distribution functions Fi α (ωi α {ω α } i ), i =,, α X 0 and the measure dµ(α). The measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) differ from the measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) on the set Ω\Ω 0, P(Ω\Ω 0 ) = 0. Let us construct the set Ω 0. Consider the set Ω 0 α = {ω α Ω α, a α i < ωi α < a α i+, i =,}, where ω α = {ω α,...,ωα } and show that P α (Ω 0 α ) =. Really, since the sequence of the sets Ω n α = {ω α Ω α, a α i < ω α i < a α i+, i =,n, a ωα i < b,i = n+,} has the probability, that is, P α (Ω n α) =, n =,2,..., and taking into account that Ω n α Ωn+ α, Ω 0 α = Ω n α, the continuity of the probability measure P α, we n= obtain P α (Ω 0 α ) =. As far as there are no more than a countable set of α for which µ(α) > 0, then there exists a countable subset X 0 X0 such that the direct sum of the sets Ω 0 α,α X 0 forms the set Ω 0 Ω, P(Ω 0 ) =. 474

15 Mathematical model of a stock market From the condition of the lemma 7 we have the recurrent relations fi α ({ω = fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω [a α i, aα i+ ) As far as = fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω, i =,, α X 0. Ω i ψ(a) α = Ω f α ({ω α } )F α (dω α ) <, then we have ψ(a) α =... fi α ({ω α } i )F α (dω)... F α i α (dωi α {ω α } i ). Ω Ω i For every t 0 [a,b) let us introduce the measurable mapping from the measurable space {Ω,F} to the measurable space {R,B(R )}. g t0 ({α,ω α }) = f α i(t 0,α) ({ω α} i(t0,α)), where i(t 0,α) = max{i,a α i t 0 }. From the condition of lemma 7 Mg t0 ({α,ω α }) = ψ(a)dµ(α) α <. X 0 Moreover, it is not difficult to see that ζ t t0 ({α,ω α }) = M{g t0 ({α,ω α }) F t }. The latter equality means that ζ t ({α,ω α }) is a local martingale since this equality is valid for any t 0 [a,b). Therefore, we can choose the sequence of stop moments t n 0 b with probability such that ζ t t n 0 ({α,ω α }) ζ t ({α,ω α }) with probability. The lemma 7 is proved. In a more general case, there holds Lemma 8. Let a measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }) on the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } belong to the subclass K 0. Suppose that for any t 0 [a,b), X 0 d α i(t 0,α) dµ(α) < for a certain probability measure dµ(α) on Σ, where d α i = sup {{ω α} i Ω i } fi α({ω α} i ), i(t 0,α) = max{i,a α i t 0 }. If for every fixed i =,, α X 0, ψ α i ({ω α } i,a α i ) = f α i ({ω α } i ), {ω α } i Ω i, 475

16 N.S.Gonchar then on the measurable space {Ω,F 0 } there exist a measure P on the σ-algebra F 0 and a modification ζ t ({α,ω α }) of the measurable mapping ζ t ({α,ω α }), such that ζ t ({α,ω α }) is a local martingale on the probability space {Ω,F,P} with respect to the flow of the σ-algebra F t, where the σ-algebras F and F t are the completion of the σ-algebras F 0 and F 0 t correspondingly with respect to the measure P. The proof of the lemma 8 is the same as the proof of the lemma 7. As before, let {Ω,F,P} be the probability space with the flow of the σ-algebras F t F on it. Suppose that ζ t ({α,ω α }) is a random process consistent with the flow of σ-algebras F t, where ζ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ζ i,α t ({ω α } i ), ζ i,α t ({ω α } i }) = fi α ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i )χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (6) (t, a α i+ ) satisfying the conditions: X 0 f α i ({ω α} i ) = Ω i+ f α i+ ({ω α} i+)f α i+ (dωα i+ {ω α} i ),... fi α α ({α,ω α } iα ) F α (dωα )...Fα i α (dωi α α {ω α } iα )dµ(α) < Ω Ω iα for every t 0 [a,b), i α = i(t 0,α) = max{i,a α i t 0 }, then ζ t ({α,ω α }) is a local martingale. This assertion can be proved the same way as lemma 7 was proved. Further on we connect with the local martingale ζ t ({α,ω α }) on {Ω,F,P} a stochastic process ζt({α,ω a α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ζ i,α t,a({ω α } i ), which is consistent with the flow of the σ-algebras F t, where ζ i,α t,a({ω α } i ) = = fi α ({ω α } i,t) Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ). (t, a α i+ ) We shall call the process ζ a t ({α,ω α}) as the process associated with the ζ t ({α,ω α }) process. 476

17 Mathematical model of a stock market Definition 3. Realization of the assotiated process ζ a t ({α,ω α}) is regular if the set is no more than the countable set. {t [a,b), ζ i,α t,a({ω α } i ) = 0, i =,} Definition 4. A local martingal ζ t ({α,ω α }) is non-singular on {Ω,F,P} if the set of regular realizations of the associated random process ζ a t ({α,ω α}) has got the probability. Lemma 9. On the probability space {Ω,F,P} there always exists a non-singular local martingale. Proof. To prove the lemma9 we construct an example of a martingaleon {Ω,F,P} that is non-singular. Let f α s (ωα s ) 0, s =,, α X0 be the measurable mapping with respect to the σ-algebra F 0 s, satisfying conditions: 0 < Ω s f α s (ω α s)f α s (dω α s {ω α } s ) <, s =,, α X 0, {ω α } s Ω s, (7) fs α (t) f Fs α s α (t {ω α } s ) (ωα s )Fα s (dωα s {ω α} s ) 0, (t, a α i+ ) Then the local martingale is not singular, where t [a α s,aα s+ ), s =,, α X0, {ω α } s Ω s. (8) ξt α ({α,ω α}) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ) ξ i,α t ({ω α } i }) = g α i ({ω α } i )χ [a α i, t](ω α i ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t,a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) g α i ({ω α} i ) = i s= g 0,α s ({ω α } s ), g 0,α s ({ω α } s ) = fs α (ω s) α fs α(ωα s )Fα s (dωα s {ω α} s ). Ω s If, for example, f α s (ωα s ) > 0, s =,, α X0, are strictly monotonous on [a α s,a α s+), then the conditions (7), (8) are satisfied. The lemma 9 is proved. 477

18 N.S.Gonchar Theorem 3. For any local martingale ζ t ({α,ω α }) given by the formula (6) and satisfying conditions sup {ω α} i Ω i f α i ({ω α } i ) = β α i <, i =,, α X 0, ϕ α Fi α i (s {ω α } (ds {ω i ) F α [a α i, aα i+ ) i (s {ω α } i ) <, {ω α} i Ω i, α X 0, the following representation ζ t ({α,ω α }) = f α (ωα )Fα (dωα )+ Ω [a,t] ψ (s ω α )dξ s ({α,ω α }), t [a,b) is valid if the local martingale ξ t ({α,ω α }) is non-singular, sup {ω α} i Ω i g α i ({ω α} i ) = = δ α i <, i =,, α X 0, and [a α i, aα i+ ) ϕ 0,α Fi α (ds {ω α } i ) i (s {ω α } i ) Fi α(s {ω α } i ) <, {ω α} i Ω i, α X 0, where ξ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ), ξ i,α t ({ω α } i }) = gi α ({ω α } i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i )χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) ψ (s ω α ) = ϕ 0,α χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (s) ϕα i (s {ω α } i ) ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ), i (s {ω α } i ) = = gi α ({ω α} i,s) Fi α(s {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω, (s, a α i+ ) ϕ α i (s {ω α } i ) = = fi α ({ω α } i,s) Fi α(s {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ). (s, a α i+ ) 478

19 Mathematical model of a stock market Proof. Let us consider on the right continuous version of the random processes ξt ({α,ω α}) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α, t ({ω α } i ), ξ i,α, t ({ω α } i ) = = Fi α(ωα i {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ [a α i, t)(ωi α ) (ωi α, aα i+ ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) ξt 2 ({α,ω α}) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α,2 t ({ω α } i ), ξ i,α,2 t ({ω α } i ) = χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) gi α ({ω α} i ) Fi α(ωα i {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω. (ωi α, aα i+ ) It is obvious that ξ t ({α,ω α }) = ξ t({α,ω α })+ξ 2 t({α,ω α }). All realizations of the random processes ξt i({α,ω α}), i =,2, have got a bounded variation on any interval [a,t], t < b. Denote by dξt({α,ω i α }), i =,2 and dξ t ({α,ω α }) the charges generated by these realizations on the σ-algebra B([a,b)). To prove the theorem 3, consider those realizations that are continuous at the points {a α i }+,α X 0. The set of realizations satisfying this condition have got the probability. The left and right limits at every point a α i, i =,, α X0 equal limξ t ({α,ω α }) = ξ i,α t a α a ({ω α} α i i ) i gi α({ω α} i )Fi α(dωα i {ω, a α i < ωi α < a α i+, {ω α} i Ω i, = [a α i, aα i+ ) gi α({ω α} i,a α i ), ωα i = a α i, {ω α} i Ω i, (9) limξ t ({α,ω α }) = g t a α i α ({ω, {ω α } i Ω i. (20) i Consider the set Ω 0 α = {ω α Ω α, a α i < ωi α < a α i+, i =,}, where ω α = {ω α,...,ωα } and show that P α(ω 0 α ) =. Really, since the sequence of the sets Ω n α = {ω α Ω α, a α i < ω α i < a α i+, i =,n, a ω α i < b,i = n+,} 479

20 N.S.Gonchar has got the probability, that is, P α (Ω n α ) =, n =,2,..., and taking into account that Ω n α Ω n+ α, Ω 0 α = Ω n α, the continuity of the probability measure P α, we n= obtain P α (Ω 0 α) =. As far as it is no more than a countable set of α for which µ(α) > 0, then there exists a countable subset X 0 X0 such that the direct sum of the sets Ω 0 α,α X0 forms the set Ω 0 Ω, P(Ω 0 ) =. Since gi α ({ω = gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω = [a α i, aα i+ ) = gi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ), i =,, α X 0, Ω i then for every {α,ω α } Ω 0 the realization of a random process ξ t ({α,ω α }) is continuousat the points {a α i } +. The charge generated by realizations of the random process ξt ({α,ω α}) on the interval [a α i,aα i+ ) is absolutely continuous with respect to the measure Fi α (dt {ω α } i ) and the Radon-Nicodym derivative equals where dξ i,α, F α t ({α,ω α }) i (dt {ω = χ [a α i,ωα i ] (t) Fi α(t (2) {ω α } i ) Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω gi α ({ω α} i,t), (t, a α i+ ) Fi α(t {ω α } i ) = lim τ t Fi α(τ {ω. The charge dξt({α,ω 2 α }) generated by realizations of the process ξt({α,ω 2 α }) on the interval [a α i,aα i+ ) is concentrated at the point t = ωα i dξt 2 ({α,ω α}) = dξ i,α,2 t ({ω α } i ) = δ(t ωi α )ϕ0,α i (ωi α {ω. (22) Let us calculate ϕ α i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) dξi,α s ({ω α} i ) = [a α i, t] + [a α i, t] [a α i, t] ϕ α i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) dξi,α, s ({ω α } i ) ϕ α i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) dξi,α,2 s ({ω α } i ) = K i,α, t ({ω α } i )+K i,α,2 t ({ω α } i ). Using (2) and the theorem 2 we have K i,α, t ({ω α } i ) = i,ωα i ] (s)ϕ α i (s {ω Fi α (ds {ω Fi α(s {ω α } i ) 480 [a α i, t] χ [aα

21 Mathematical model of a stock market = Fi α(ωα i {ω fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ [a α i, t)(ωi α ) (ωi α, aα i+ ) + Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ) (t, a α i+ ) i (dωi α {ω α } i ). (a α i, aα i+ ) f α i ({ω α } i )F α Further, K i,α,2 t ({ω α } i ) = χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) fi α ({ω α } i ) Fi α(ωα i {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dω α i {ω α } i ). (ωi α, aα i+ ) Therefore, [a α i, t] ϕ α i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) dξi,α s ({ω α } i ) = = fi α ({ω α } i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) +χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ) Fi α(t {ω fi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ) (t, a α i+ ) i (dωα i {ω. [a α i, aα i+ ) f α i ({ω α} i )F α Taking the limit t a α i+ we obtain ϕ α i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) dξi,α s ({ω α } i ) = where [a α i, aα i+ ) = f α i ({ω α } i ) f α i ({ω α } i ), i =,, f0({ω α α } 0 ) = f({ω α α } )F α (dω) α = (a α, aα 2 ) Ω f α ({ω α } )F α (dω α ). Granting this and the definition of ψ (s ω α ) we obtain f α (ωα )Fα (dωα )+ ψ (s ω α )dξ s ({α,ω α }) = ζ i,α t ({ω α } i ) Ω The theorem 3 is proved. [a,t] = ζ t ({α,ω α }), t [a α i,aα i+ ). 48

22 N.S.Gonchar Theorem 4. Let ξ 0 t ({α,ω α}) be a local martingale on {Ω,F,P}, ξt 0 ({α,ω α}) = ξ i,α χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ), t ({ω α } i }) = gi α ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) satisfying conditions: where sup gi α ({ω α} i ) = βi α <, i =,, α X 0, {ω α} i Ω i Fi α (ds {ω α } i ) i (s {ω α } i ) Fi α(s {ω α } i ) <, [a α i, aα i+ ) ϕ 0,α {ω α } i Ω i, i =,, α X 0, ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) = = gi α ({ω α} i,s) Fi α(s {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω. (s, a α i+ ) The random process ξ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)f α (ξ i,α t ({ω α } i )) belongs to the subclass K 0 if the family of functions f α (x) > 0, x R, α X 0, are strictly monotonous, sup f α (x) = fα <, inf x R x R f α (x) = fα 2 > 0, moreover, sup i sup sup {ω α} i Ω i s [a α i,aα i+ ) Fi α (s {ω α } i ) Fi α(s {ω α } i ) < fα 2. f α Proof. To prove the theorem 4 it is sufficient to verify the fulfillment of the conditions of definition 2. The condition is valid, because ψ α i ({ω α} i,t) = f α (T α i (t {ω ) is continuous on the right, where Ti α (t {ω α } i ) = Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ). (t, a α i+ ) 482

23 Mathematical model of a stock market Moreover, var t [a α i, τ]ψα i ({ω α } i,t) f α 0,α ϕ [a α i, τ] Fi α i (s {ω α } i ) (ds {ω Fi α(s {ω α } i ) <, τ [a α i,aα i+ ), {ω α} i Ω i, α X 0. The Radon-Nicodym derivative of the charge ψ α i ({ω α } i,dt), generated by ψ α i ({ω α} i,t), equals Thus, ψi α({ω α} i,dt) Fi α(dt {ω = f α (Tα i (t {ω )ϕ 0,α i (t {ω α } i ) Fi α(t. {ω α } i ) γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) = = [a α i, t] [a α i, t] ψ α i ({ω α} i,dτ) ψ α i ({ω α} i,τ) f α (g α i ({ω α} i,τ)) f α(t i α (τ {ω α } i ))Fi α (dτ {ω α } i ) U({ω α } i,τ)[ Fi α(τ {ω α } i )] is non-negative and monotonously non-decreasing on [a α i,a α i+), where U({ω α } i,τ) = Further, γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) fα f α 2 0 f α(g α i ({ω α } i,τ)+z[t α i (τ {ω α } i ) g α i ({ω α } i,τ)])dz. sup i lim γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) fα 2 t a α i+ f α lim t a α i sup sup {ω α} i Ω i lim t a α i+ [a α i, t] s [a α i,aα i+ ) Fi α(s {ω Fi α(s {ω α } i ) <. Fi α(dτ {ω Fi α(τ {ω α } i ) =, γ i,α ({ω α } i,t) = 0, {ω α } i Ω i, α X 0. (c) is evident from (b) and boundedness of ψ α i ({ω α} i ). At last [a α i,aα i+ ) f α (g α i ({ω α} i,t)) exp{ γ i,α ({ω α } i,t )}γ i,α ({ω α } i,dt) The theorem 4 is proved. e(β α i fα +f α(0)). 483

24 N.S.Gonchar 5. Options and their pricing We assume that {Ω,F,P} is a full probability space, generated by the family of distribution functions Fi α (ωi α {ω α } i ), i =,, α X 0 and a measure dµ(α) on the σ-algebra Σ. Further on we assume that X 0 is a space of possible hypothesis each of which may occur with probability µ(α), that is, an evolution of stock price can come by one of the possible scenario. This scenario is determined by sequence α and a probability space {Ω α,fα 0,P α}. Theorem 5. Let φ({α,ω α }) = φ α ({ω α } ) be a random value on the probability space {Ω,F,P}, satisfying conditions: ) φ α ({ω α } ) C α <, α X 0, C α dµ(α) < ; X 0 2) there exists t α i [a α i,aα i+ ) such that φ α ({ω α } i,s,{ω α } [i+,] ) φ α ({ω α } i,s 2,{ω α } [i+,] ) C α i Fα i (s {ω α } i ) F α i (s 2 {ω α } i ) εi α, ε i α > 0, s, s 2 [t α i,aα i+ ), C α i <, i =,, {ω α } i Ω i, {ω α } [i+,] Ω i, α X 0. Further, let ξ 0 t({α,ω α }) be a local non-singular martingale on {Ω,F,P}, ξt({α,ω 0 α }) = ξ i,α χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ), t ({ω α } i }) = gi α ({ω α} i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) satisfying conditions sup gi α ({ω α } i ) = βi α <, i =,, α X 0, {ω α} i Ω i 0,α Fi α ρi (s {ω α } i ) (ds {ω F α [a α i, aα i+ ) i (s {ω α } i ) <, {ω α} i Ω i, α X 0, ρ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) = = gi α ({ω α} i,s) Fi α(s {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω, (s, a α i+ ) If the random process has got the form 484 ξ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)f α (ξ i,α t ({ω α } i )),

25 Mathematical model of a stock market where a family of functions f α (x) > 0, x R, α X 0, is such that each of the functions f α (x) is strictly fulfillment, sup f α(x) = f α <, inf α(x) = f α x R x R f 2 > 0, and Fi α sup sup sup (s {ω i {ω α} i Ω i s [a α i,aα i+ ) Fi α(s {ω α } i ) < fα 2, f α then there exists a measure P on {Ω,F 0 }, generated by a certain family of distribution functions F α, i (ωi α {ω α } i ), i =,, α X 0, a probability measure dµ (α) on the σ-algebra Σ and a modification ξ t ({α,ω α }) of the the random process ξ t ({α,ω α }) such that ξ t ({α,ω α }) is a local non-singular martingale on the probability space {Ω,F,P } with respect to the flow of the σ-algebras Ft, where the σ-algebras F and Ft are the completion of the σ-algebras F 0 and Ft 0 correspondingly with respect to the measure P. Moreover, for the regular martingale M {φ({α,ω α }) Ft } on the probability space {Ω,F,P } the representation M {φ({α,ω α }) F t } = Mα φα ({ω α } )+ ψ (s ω α )d ξ s ({α,ω α }), t [a,b) is valid, where = f α (g α i ({ω α} i,s)) [a,t] ψ (s ω α ) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (s) ϕα i (s {ω α } i ) ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ), F α, ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) = f α (gi α i (s {ω α } i ) ({ω α} i ))F α, i (dωi α {ω, (s, a α i+ ) ϕ α i (s {ω α } i ) = = φ α i ({ω α} i,s) F α, φ α i i (s {ω α } i ) ({ω α} i )F α, i (dωi α {ω, (s, a α i+ ) φ α i ({ω α } i ) =... φ α ({ω α } i,{ω α } [i+,] ) Ω i+ Ω F α, i+ (dωα i+ {ω α} i )... F α, (dωα {ω α} ). Proof. The conditions of the theorem 5 guarantee the monotonous of the conditions of the theorem 4. Therefore the random process ξ t ({α,ω α }) belongs to the subclass K 0. Moreover, ψi α ({ω α } i,a α i ) = f α (ξ i,α a ({ω α} α i i )) = f α i (dωi α {ω α } i ) = (a α i, aα i+ ) g α i ({ω α } i )F α 485

26 N.S.Gonchar = f α (g α i ({ω ) = f α i ({ω with probability on the probability space {Ω,F,P}, since gi ({ω α α } i ) = gi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ) (a α i, aα i+ ) with probability. Further, X 0 f α (v(α))dµ (α) <, where dµ (α) = u(α)dµ(α), v(α) = (a α i, aα i+ ) g α (ω α )F α (dω α ), u(α) = χ A(α)+[f α (v(α))] χ X 0 \A(α), D D = {χ A (α)+[f α (v(α))] χ X0\A(α)}dµ(α), X 0 χ A (α) is the characteristic function of the set A = {α, f α (v(α)) }. Based on the lemma 7 there exists a measure P on the σ-algebra F 0, generated by a certain family of distribution functions F α, i (ωi α {ω, i =,, α X 0 and the measure dµ (α) on σ-algebra Σ such that the random process + F α, ξ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t) ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ), ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ) = f α (gi α ({ω α } i ))χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) f α (gi α i (t {ω α } i ) ({ω α} i ))F α, i (dωi α {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (t, a α i+ ) i =,, α X 0, is a modification of the random process ξ t ({α,ω α }) on the probability space {Ω,F,P }. Since ξ 0 t ({α,ω α}) is also a local non-singular martingale, then ξ t ({α,ω α }) is also a local non-singular martingale because 486 {t [a,b), ξi,α t,a({ω α } i ) = 0, i =,} {t [a,b), ξ i,α t,a({ω α } i ) = 0, i =,},

27 Mathematical model of a stock market due to the strict monotony of f α (x), where = f α (g α i ({ω α } i )) F α, ξ i,α t,a({ω α } i ) = f α (g α α, i ({ω α } i ))Fi (dωi α {ω α } i ) i (t {ω α } i ) (t, a α i+ ) = f α (gi α ({ω α} i )) f α (Ti α (t {ω ), Ti α (t {ω α } i ) = Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α } i )Fi α (dωi α {ω α } i ), (t, a α i+ ) ξ i,α t,a({ω α } i ) = g α i ({ω α } i ) T α i (t {ω α } i ). To finish the proof of the theorem 5 it is sufficient to verify the monotonous of the conditions of the theorem 3. Really, [fα ]2 f α 2 +C α i 0,α ϕi (s {ω α } i ) [a α i, aα i+ ) F α, i (ds {ω α } i ) F α, i (s {ω α } i ) 0,α Fi α ρi (s {ω α } i ) (ds {ω F α [a α i, aα i+ ) i (s {ω α } i ) <, {ω α } i Ω i, α X 0. [a α i, aα i+ ) ϕ α i (s {ω α} i ) 2C α [a α i, tα i ] ( Fi α (s {ω ) εi α [t α i, aα i+ ) F α, i (ds {ω α } i ) F α, i (s {ω α } i ) F α, i (ds {ω α } i ) F α, i (s {ω α } i ) F α, i (ds {ω α } i ) F α, i (s {ω α } i ) <, because the first integral is finite and the second integral is finite since γ i,α ψi α ({ω α } i,dτ) ({ω α } i,t) = ψi α({ω α} i,τ) f α (gi α({ω α} i,τ)) = [a α i, t] = [a α i, t] [a α i, t] F α, i (dτ {ω α } i ) F α, i (τ {ω α } i ) f α (Tα i (τ {ω )Fi α(dτ {ω U({ω α } i,τ)[ Fi α(τ {ω α } i )]. 487

28 N.S.Gonchar Therefore ( Fi α (s {ω ) εi α [t α i, aα i+ ) F α, i (ds {ω α } i ) F α, i (s {ω α } i ) fα. ε i αf2 α The theorem 5 is proved. Then we assume that interval [a,b) coincides with the interval [0,T), that is a = 0, b = T. The time T is the terminal time of monotonous of the option. Definition 5. A stock marketis effective on the time interval [0,T), if there is a certain probability space {Ω,F,P}, constructed above, a random process ξt 0({α,ω α}) on it, describing the evolution of the average price of stocks such that ξt({α,ω 0 α })e rt is a non-negative uniformly integrable and non-singular martingale on {Ω, F, P} with respect to the flow of the σ-algebras F t, where the σ-algebras F and F t are the completion of the σ-algebras F 0 and Ft 0 with respect to the measure P on F 0, generated by the family of distribution functions Fi α(ωα i {ω. The random process ξt({α,ω 0 α }) has the form ξt 0 ({α,ω α}) = B 0 e rt χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)ξ i,α t ({ω α } i ), (23) ξ i,α t ({ω α } i }) = gi α ({ω α } i )χ [a α i, t](ωi α ) + Fi α(t {ω gi α ({ω α} i )Fi α (dωα i {ω χ (t, a α i+ )(ωi α ), (24) (t, a α i+ ) where r is an interest rate, the evolution of price of a stock being described by a certain random process S t ({α,ω α }) = S 0e rt V α χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)f α (ξ i,α t ({ω α } i )), V α = f α (M α φ α ({ω α } )) (25) for a certain family of functions f α (x) > 0, x R, α X 0, which are strictly fulfillment, sup f α (x) = fα <, inf x R x R f α (x) = fα 2 > 0, moreover, sup i sup sup {ω α} i Ω i s [a α i,aα i+ ) Fi α(s {ω Fi α(s {ω α } i ) < fα 2. (26) f α The limit φ α ({ω α } )) = limξt 0 ({α,ω t T α})b0 e rt satisfies the conditions: ) φ α ({ω α } ) C α <, α X 0, C α dµ(α) < ; X 0 2) there exists t α i [a α i,aα i+ ) such that 488 φ α ({ω α } i,s,{ω α } [i+,] ) φ α ({ω α } i,s 2,{ω α } [i+,] )

29 Mathematical model of a stock market C α i Fα i (s {ω α } i ) F α i (s 2 {ω α } i ) εi α, ε i α > 0, s, s 2 [t α i,aα i+ ), C α i <, i =,, {ω α } i Ω i, {ω α } [i+,] ) Ω i, α X 0. Let us consider an economic agent on the stock market, who acts an as investor, that is, he or she wants to multiply his or her capital using the possibilities of the stock market. We assume that the stock market is effective and the evolution of a stock price occurs according to the formula (25). We assume that the evolution of non-risky active price occurs according to the law B(t) = B 0 e rt, (27) where r is an interest rate, B 0 is an initial capital of the investor on a deposit. Definition 6. A stochastic process δ t ({α,ω α }) belongs to the class A 0, if b α, δ t ({α,ω α }) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (t)δ i,α t ({ω α } i ), δ i,α t ({ω α } i ) = b α, i ({ω α } i,t)χ [a α i, t](ω α i )+bα,2 i ({ω α } i,t)χ (t, a α i+ )(ω α i ), i ({ω α } i,t) is a measurable mapping from the measurable space {Ω i, F i} 0 to the measurable space {R,B(R )} at every fixed t from the interval [0,T), b α,2 i ({ω α } i,t) is a measurable mapping from the measurable space {Ω i, F i 0 } to the measurable space {R,B(R )} at every fixed t [0,T). Moreover, b α, i ({ω α } i,t) is a bounded measurable mapping from the measurable space {[0,T),B([0,T))} to the measurable space {R,B(R )} at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i, b α,2 i ({ω α } i,t) is a bounded measurable mapping from {[0,T),B([0,T))} to {R,B(R )} at every fixed {ω α } i Ω i. Let the capital of an investor X t ({α,ω α }) at time t equal X t ({α,ω α }) = B(t)β t ({α,ω α })+γ t ({α,ω α })S t ({α,ω α }), (28) where the stochastic processes β t ({α,ω α }) and γ t ({α,ω α }) belong to the class A 0. The pair π t = {β t ({α,ω α }),γ t ({α,ω α })} is called the financial strategy of the investor. The capital of the investor with the financial strategy π t will be denoted by X π t ({α,ω α }). Definition 7. A financial strategy π t = {β t ({α,ω α }),γ t ({α,ω α })} of an investor is called self-financing if the random processes β t ({α,ω α }) and γ t ({α,ω α }) belong to the class A 0, for the investor capital Xt π({α,ω α}) the representation Xt π ({α,ω α}) = X0 π (α)+ β τ ({α,ω α })db(τ)+ γ τ ({α,ω α })ds τ ({α,ω α }) (29) [0,t] [0,t] is valid, the discounted capital Y π t ({α,ω α}) = Xπ t ({α,ω α}) B(t) 489

30 N.S.Gonchar belongs to the class of local martingale on the probability space {Ω,F,P } with respect to the flow of the σ-algebras F t, M X π t ({α,ω α }) <, where F,P and F t are constructed in the theorem 5. A class of self-financing strategy is denoted by SF. Lemma 0. Let a financial strategy π t = {β t ({α,ω α }),γ t ({α,ω α })} be self-financing, then for the investor capital the representations Xt π ({α,ω α}) = X0 π (α)+ β τ ({α,ω α })db(τ)+ γ τ ({α,ω α })ds τ ({α,ω α }) (30) [0,t] X π t ({α,ω α}) = e rt X π 0 (α)+b 0e rt [0,t] γ τ ({α,ω α })ds 0 τ ({α,ω α}) (3) are equivalent, where [0,t] St 0 ({α,ω α}) = S 0 χ [a α B 0 V i, a α i+ ) (t)f α (ξ i,α t ({ω α } i )). (32) α Proof. Since Xt π({α,ω α}) is a process of a bounded variation on any interval [0,t], therefore from (3) and lemma Xt π ({α,ω α}) = X0 π (α)+ X0 α +B 0 γ τ ({α,ω α })dsτ 0 ({α,ω α}) de rt Since = X0(α)+ π [0,t] +B 0 [0,t] [0,t] [0,t] e rτ γ τ ({α,ω α })ds 0 τ ({α,ω α}) X τ ({α,ω α }) db(τ) B(τ) + [0,t] S t ({α,ω α }) = B(t)S 0 t ({α,ω α}), B(τ)γ τ ({α,ω α })ds 0 τ({α,ω α }). ds t ({α,ω α }) = S 0 t ({α,ω α})db(t)+b(t)ds 0 t ({α,ω α}), (33) therefore, taking into account (28) and (33), we obtain Xt π ({α,ω α}) = X0 π (α)+ db(τ) β τ ({α,ω α })db(τ)+ B(τ) γ τ({α,ω α })S τ ({α,ω α }) + [0,t] γ τ ({α,ω α })ds τ ({α,ω α }) [0,t] γ τ ({α,ω α })S 0 τ ({α,ω α})db(τ) [0,t] [0,t] 490

31 Mathematical model of a stock market = X π 0 (α)+ β τ ({α,ω α })db(τ)+ γ τ ({α,ω α })ds τ ({α,ω α }). [0,t] This proves the lemma 0 in one direction. Applying the same argument in the inverse direction we obtain the proof of the lemma 0. Denote by SF R a set of self-financing strategies satisfying the conditions [0,t] M {Y π t ({α,ω α}) F t } M {R F t }, M R <, where R is a non-negative random value on {Ω,F,P }. Lemma. Let π t = {β t ({α,ω α }),γ t ({α,ω α })} be a self-financing strategy, that is, π t SF R, then {Yt π,ft,t [0,T]} is a supermartingale and for any stop time τ and τ 2 such that P (τ τ 2 ) = the inequality is valid. M {Y π τ 2 ({α,ω α }) F τ } Y π τ ({α,ω α }) The proof is similar to the proof of the analogous lemma in [2]. Corollary 3. If π t SF R, then for any stop time τ 0, P (τ < ) = M Y π τ ({α,ω α}) Y π 0 (α) = Xπ 0(α) B 0. Definition 8. A self-financing strategy π t is an arbitrage strategy on [0,T], if from that X π 0(α) 0, X π T({α,ω α }) 0 it follows that X π T ({α,ω α}) > 0 with a positive probability. Lemma 2. Any strategy π t SF R, where R is non-negative and integrable random value on probability space, is not arbitrage strategy. The proof of the lemma is analogous to the proof of the similar lemma in [2]. Let φ T = φ T ({α,ω α }) = φ α T ({ω α} )bef 0 measurablerandomvalueontheprobability space {Ω,F 0,P}. Definition 9. A self-financingstrategy π t SF R is (x α,φ T )-hedge for the European type option if the capital X π t ({α,ω α}), corresponding to this strategy is such that X π 0(α) = x α and with probability with respect to the measure P X π T({α,ω α }) φ T ({α,ω α }). (x α,φ T )-hedge πt SF R is called minimal if for any (x α,φ T )-hedge π t SF R the inequality XT({α,ω π α }) XT π ({α,ω α }) is valid. 49

32 N.S.Gonchar Then we consider self-financing strategies, belonging to SF 0, that is, in this case X π t ({α,ω α }) 0. Definition 0. Let H T (x α,φ T ) be the set of (x α,φ T )-hedges from SF 0. Investment value is called the value where is the empty set. C α T(φ T ) = inf{x α 0, H T (x α,φ T ) }, α X 0, The main problem is to calculate C α T (φ T) and to find an expression for the portfolio of an investor π t at every moment of time t the initial capital of which is xα. Further on we assume that T <, then lim S t({α,ω α }) = S T ({α,ω α }) = S 0e rt f α (φ({α,ω α })). t T V α Theorem 6. Let a stock market be effective, the evolution of a risky active price comes according to the formula (25) and the evolution of non-risky active price occur by (27). If f(x) is a certain function such that f(x ) f(x 2 ) C x x 2 and the paying function at terminal time T is given by the formula f T ({α,ω α }) = f(s T ({α,ω α })), moreover, the conditions fc α α dµ(α) <, V α X 0 X 0 f α (0) V α dµ(α) <, are valid, then the minimal hedge π t exists, evolution of the capital investor X t ({α,ω α}), option price X 0 (α) and self-financial strategy {β t ({α,ω α}), γ t({α,ω α })} corresponding to the minimal hedge π t are given by the formulas X t({α,ω α }) = e r(t T) M {f(s T ({α,ω α })) F t}, (34) where X 0(α) = e rt M αf(s T ({α,ω α })), γ t({α,ω α }) = ψ (t {ω} α ), (35) βt({α,ω α }) = X t ({α,ω α}) γt ({α,ω α})s t ({α,ω α }), (36) B(t) F α, ψ (s ω α ) = χ [a α i, a α i+ ) (s) ϕα i (s {ω ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ), ϕ 0,α i (s {ω α } i ) = = f α (gi α ({ω α} i,s)) f α (g α α, i ({ω α } i ))Fi (dωi α {ω α } i ), i (s {ω α } i ) (s, a α i+ ) 492

2 Composition. Invertible Mappings

2 Composition. Invertible Mappings Arkansas Tech University MATH 4033: Elementary Modern Algebra Dr. Marcel B. Finan Composition. Invertible Mappings In this section we discuss two procedures for creating new mappings from old ones, namely,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Ordinal Arithmetic: Addition, Multiplication, Exponentiation and Limit

Ordinal Arithmetic: Addition, Multiplication, Exponentiation and Limit Ordinal Arithmetic: Addition, Multiplication, Exponentiation and Limit Ting Zhang Stanford May 11, 2001 Stanford, 5/11/2001 1 Outline Ordinal Classification Ordinal Addition Ordinal Multiplication Ordinal

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Every set of first-order formulas is equivalent to an independent set

Every set of first-order formulas is equivalent to an independent set Every set of first-order formulas is equivalent to an independent set May 6, 2008 Abstract A set of first-order formulas, whatever the cardinality of the set of symbols, is equivalent to an independent

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

EE512: Error Control Coding

EE512: Error Control Coding EE512: Error Control Coding Solution for Assignment on Finite Fields February 16, 2007 1. (a) Addition and Multiplication tables for GF (5) and GF (7) are shown in Tables 1 and 2. + 0 1 2 3 4 0 0 1 2 3

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

C.S. 430 Assignment 6, Sample Solutions

C.S. 430 Assignment 6, Sample Solutions C.S. 430 Assignment 6, Sample Solutions Paul Liu November 15, 2007 Note that these are sample solutions only; in many cases there were many acceptable answers. 1 Reynolds Problem 10.1 1.1 Normal-order

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Reminders: linear functions

Reminders: linear functions Reminders: linear functions Let U and V be vector spaces over the same field F. Definition A function f : U V is linear if for every u 1, u 2 U, f (u 1 + u 2 ) = f (u 1 ) + f (u 2 ), and for every u U

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Uniform Convergence of Fourier Series Michael Taylor

Uniform Convergence of Fourier Series Michael Taylor Uniform Convergence of Fourier Series Michael Taylor Given f L 1 T 1 ), we consider the partial sums of the Fourier series of f: N 1) S N fθ) = ˆfk)e ikθ. k= N A calculation gives the Dirichlet formula

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Example Sheet 3 Solutions

Example Sheet 3 Solutions Example Sheet 3 Solutions. i Regular Sturm-Liouville. ii Singular Sturm-Liouville mixed boundary conditions. iii Not Sturm-Liouville ODE is not in Sturm-Liouville form. iv Regular Sturm-Liouville note

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

ST5224: Advanced Statistical Theory II

ST5224: Advanced Statistical Theory II ST5224: Advanced Statistical Theory II 2014/2015: Semester II Tutorial 7 1. Let X be a sample from a population P and consider testing hypotheses H 0 : P = P 0 versus H 1 : P = P 1, where P j is a known

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Lecture 2: Dirac notation and a review of linear algebra Read Sakurai chapter 1, Baym chatper 3

Lecture 2: Dirac notation and a review of linear algebra Read Sakurai chapter 1, Baym chatper 3 Lecture 2: Dirac notation and a review of linear algebra Read Sakurai chapter 1, Baym chatper 3 1 State vector space and the dual space Space of wavefunctions The space of wavefunctions is the set of all

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Fourier Series. MATH 211, Calculus II. J. Robert Buchanan. Spring Department of Mathematics

Fourier Series. MATH 211, Calculus II. J. Robert Buchanan. Spring Department of Mathematics Fourier Series MATH 211, Calculus II J. Robert Buchanan Department of Mathematics Spring 2018 Introduction Not all functions can be represented by Taylor series. f (k) (c) A Taylor series f (x) = (x c)

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Fractional Colorings and Zykov Products of graphs

Fractional Colorings and Zykov Products of graphs Fractional Colorings and Zykov Products of graphs Who? Nichole Schimanski When? July 27, 2011 Graphs A graph, G, consists of a vertex set, V (G), and an edge set, E(G). V (G) is any finite set E(G) is

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential Equations Let a (t), a 2 (t),..., a nn (t), b (t), b 2 (t),..., b n (t) be continuous functions on the interval I. The system of n first-order differential equations

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM Solutions to Question 1 a) The cumulative distribution function of T conditional on N n is Pr T t N n) Pr max X 1,..., X N ) t N n) Pr max

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Nowhere-zero flows Let be a digraph, Abelian group. A Γ-circulation in is a mapping : such that, where, and : tail in X, head in

Nowhere-zero flows Let be a digraph, Abelian group. A Γ-circulation in is a mapping : such that, where, and : tail in X, head in Nowhere-zero flows Let be a digraph, Abelian group. A Γ-circulation in is a mapping : such that, where, and : tail in X, head in : tail in X, head in A nowhere-zero Γ-flow is a Γ-circulation such that

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Solution Series 9. i=1 x i and i=1 x i.

Solution Series 9. i=1 x i and i=1 x i. Lecturer: Prof. Dr. Mete SONER Coordinator: Yilin WANG Solution Series 9 Q1. Let α, β >, the p.d.f. of a beta distribution with parameters α and β is { Γ(α+β) Γ(α)Γ(β) f(x α, β) xα 1 (1 x) β 1 for < x

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Math 446 Homework 3 Solutions. (1). (i): Reverse triangle inequality for metrics: Let (X, d) be a metric space and let x, y, z X.

Math 446 Homework 3 Solutions. (1). (i): Reverse triangle inequality for metrics: Let (X, d) be a metric space and let x, y, z X. Math 446 Homework 3 Solutions. (1). (i): Reverse triangle inequalit for metrics: Let (X, d) be a metric space and let x,, z X. Prove that d(x, z) d(, z) d(x, ). (ii): Reverse triangle inequalit for norms:

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Phys460.nb Solution for the t-dependent Schrodinger s equation How did we find the solution? (not required)

Phys460.nb Solution for the t-dependent Schrodinger s equation How did we find the solution? (not required) Phys460.nb 81 ψ n (t) is still the (same) eigenstate of H But for tdependent H. The answer is NO. 5.5.5. Solution for the tdependent Schrodinger s equation If we assume that at time t 0, the electron starts

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Other Test Constructions: Likelihood Ratio & Bayes Tests

Other Test Constructions: Likelihood Ratio & Bayes Tests Other Test Constructions: Likelihood Ratio & Bayes Tests Side-Note: So far we have seen a few approaches for creating tests such as Neyman-Pearson Lemma ( most powerful tests of H 0 : θ = θ 0 vs H 1 :

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Statistical Inference I Locally most powerful tests

Statistical Inference I Locally most powerful tests Statistical Inference I Locally most powerful tests Shirsendu Mukherjee Department of Statistics, Asutosh College, Kolkata, India. shirsendu st@yahoo.co.in So far we have treated the testing of one-sided

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

12. Radon-Nikodym Theorem

12. Radon-Nikodym Theorem Tutorial 12: Radon-Nikodym Theorem 1 12. Radon-Nikodym Theorem In the following, (Ω, F) is an arbitrary measurable space. Definition 96 Let μ and ν be two (possibly complex) measures on (Ω, F). We say

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

CHAPTER 25 SOLVING EQUATIONS BY ITERATIVE METHODS

CHAPTER 25 SOLVING EQUATIONS BY ITERATIVE METHODS CHAPTER 5 SOLVING EQUATIONS BY ITERATIVE METHODS EXERCISE 104 Page 8 1. Find the positive root of the equation x + 3x 5 = 0, correct to 3 significant figures, using the method of bisection. Let f(x) =

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

ω ω ω ω ω ω+2 ω ω+2 + ω ω ω ω+2 + ω ω+1 ω ω+2 2 ω ω ω ω ω ω ω ω+1 ω ω2 ω ω2 + ω ω ω2 + ω ω ω ω2 + ω ω+1 ω ω2 + ω ω+1 + ω ω ω ω2 + ω

ω ω ω ω ω ω+2 ω ω+2 + ω ω ω ω+2 + ω ω+1 ω ω+2 2 ω ω ω ω ω ω ω ω+1 ω ω2 ω ω2 + ω ω ω2 + ω ω ω ω2 + ω ω+1 ω ω2 + ω ω+1 + ω ω ω ω2 + ω 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 ω ω + 1 ω + 2 ω + 3 ω + 4 ω2 ω2 + 1 ω2 + 2 ω2 + 3 ω3 ω3 + 1 ω3 + 2 ω4 ω4 + 1 ω5 ω 2 ω 2 + 1 ω 2 + 2 ω 2 + ω ω 2 + ω + 1 ω 2 + ω2 ω 2 2 ω 2 2 + 1 ω 2 2 + ω ω 2 3 ω 3 ω 3 + 1 ω 3 + ω ω 3 +

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Partial Differential Equations in Biology The boundary element method. March 26, 2013

Partial Differential Equations in Biology The boundary element method. March 26, 2013 The boundary element method March 26, 203 Introduction and notation The problem: u = f in D R d u = ϕ in Γ D u n = g on Γ N, where D = Γ D Γ N, Γ D Γ N = (possibly, Γ D = [Neumann problem] or Γ N = [Dirichlet

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Homework 3 Solutions

Homework 3 Solutions Homework 3 Solutions Igor Yanovsky (Math 151A TA) Problem 1: Compute the absolute error and relative error in approximations of p by p. (Use calculator!) a) p π, p 22/7; b) p π, p 3.141. Solution: For

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Solutions to Exercise Sheet 5

Solutions to Exercise Sheet 5 Solutions to Eercise Sheet 5 jacques@ucsd.edu. Let X and Y be random variables with joint pdf f(, y) = 3y( + y) where and y. Determine each of the following probabilities. Solutions. a. P (X ). b. P (X

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM

SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM SOLUTIONS TO MATH38181 EXTREME VALUES AND FINANCIAL RISK EXAM Solutions to Question 1 a) The cumulative distribution function of T conditional on N n is Pr (T t N n) Pr (max (X 1,..., X N ) t N n) Pr (max

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

SOME PROPERTIES OF FUZZY REAL NUMBERS

SOME PROPERTIES OF FUZZY REAL NUMBERS Sahand Communications in Mathematical Analysis (SCMA) Vol. 3 No. 1 (2016), 21-27 http://scma.maragheh.ac.ir SOME PROPERTIES OF FUZZY REAL NUMBERS BAYAZ DARABY 1 AND JAVAD JAFARI 2 Abstract. In the mathematical

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

ORDINAL ARITHMETIC JULIAN J. SCHLÖDER

ORDINAL ARITHMETIC JULIAN J. SCHLÖDER ORDINAL ARITHMETIC JULIAN J. SCHLÖDER Abstract. We define ordinal arithmetic and show laws of Left- Monotonicity, Associativity, Distributivity, some minor related properties and the Cantor Normal Form.

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

4.6 Autoregressive Moving Average Model ARMA(1,1)

4.6 Autoregressive Moving Average Model ARMA(1,1) 84 CHAPTER 4. STATIONARY TS MODELS 4.6 Autoregressive Moving Average Model ARMA(,) This section is an introduction to a wide class of models ARMA(p,q) which we will consider in more detail later in this

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Concrete Mathematics Exercises from 30 September 2016

Concrete Mathematics Exercises from 30 September 2016 Concrete Mathematics Exercises from 30 September 2016 Silvio Capobianco Exercise 1.7 Let H(n) = J(n + 1) J(n). Equation (1.8) tells us that H(2n) = 2, and H(2n+1) = J(2n+2) J(2n+1) = (2J(n+1) 1) (2J(n)+1)

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Math221: HW# 1 solutions

Math221: HW# 1 solutions Math: HW# solutions Andy Royston October, 5 7.5.7, 3 rd Ed. We have a n = b n = a = fxdx = xdx =, x cos nxdx = x sin nx n sin nxdx n = cos nx n = n n, x sin nxdx = x cos nx n + cos nxdx n cos n = + sin

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Mean-Variance Analysis

Mean-Variance Analysis Mean-Variance Analysis Jan Schneider McCombs School of Business University of Texas at Austin Jan Schneider Mean-Variance Analysis Beta Representation of the Risk Premium risk premium E t [Rt t+τ ] R1

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval

Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential. be continuous functions on the interval Chapter 6: Systems of Linear Differential Equations Let a (t), a 2 (t),..., a nn (t), b (t), b 2 (t),..., b n (t) be continuous functions on the interval I. The system of n first-order differential equations

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Απόκριση σε Μοναδιαία Ωστική Δύναμη (Unit Impulse) Απόκριση σε Δυνάμεις Αυθαίρετα Μεταβαλλόμενες με το Χρόνο. Απόστολος Σ.

Απόκριση σε Μοναδιαία Ωστική Δύναμη (Unit Impulse) Απόκριση σε Δυνάμεις Αυθαίρετα Μεταβαλλόμενες με το Χρόνο. Απόστολος Σ. Απόκριση σε Δυνάμεις Αυθαίρετα Μεταβαλλόμενες με το Χρόνο The time integral of a force is referred to as impulse, is determined by and is obtained from: Newton s 2 nd Law of motion states that the action

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Section 8.3 Trigonometric Equations

Section 8.3 Trigonometric Equations 99 Section 8. Trigonometric Equations Objective 1: Solve Equations Involving One Trigonometric Function. In this section and the next, we will exple how to solving equations involving trigonometric functions.

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Inverse trigonometric functions & General Solution of Trigonometric Equations. ------------------ ----------------------------- -----------------

Inverse trigonometric functions & General Solution of Trigonometric Equations. ------------------ ----------------------------- ----------------- Inverse trigonometric functions & General Solution of Trigonometric Equations. 1. Sin ( ) = a) b) c) d) Ans b. Solution : Method 1. Ans a: 17 > 1 a) is rejected. w.k.t Sin ( sin ) = d is rejected. If sin

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

k A = [k, k]( )[a 1, a 2 ] = [ka 1,ka 2 ] 4For the division of two intervals of confidence in R +

k A = [k, k]( )[a 1, a 2 ] = [ka 1,ka 2 ] 4For the division of two intervals of confidence in R + Chapter 3. Fuzzy Arithmetic 3- Fuzzy arithmetic: ~Addition(+) and subtraction (-): Let A = [a and B = [b, b in R If x [a and y [b, b than x+y [a +b +b Symbolically,we write A(+)B = [a (+)[b, b = [a +b

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

6.3 Forecasting ARMA processes

6.3 Forecasting ARMA processes 122 CHAPTER 6. ARMA MODELS 6.3 Forecasting ARMA processes The purpose of forecasting is to predict future values of a TS based on the data collected to the present. In this section we will discuss a linear

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Online Appendix I. 1 1+r ]}, Bψ = {ψ : Y E A S S}, B W = +(1 s)[1 m (1,0) (b, e, a, ψ (0,a ) (e, a, s); q, ψ, W )]}, (29) exp( U(d,a ) (i, x; q)

Online Appendix I. 1 1+r ]}, Bψ = {ψ : Y E A S S}, B W = +(1 s)[1 m (1,0) (b, e, a, ψ (0,a ) (e, a, s); q, ψ, W )]}, (29) exp( U(d,a ) (i, x; q) Online Appendix I Appendix D Additional Existence Proofs Denote B q = {q : A E A S [0, +r ]}, Bψ = {ψ : Y E A S S}, B W = {W : I E A S R}. I slightly abuse the notation by defining B q (L q ) the subset

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Lecture 13 - Root Space Decomposition II

Lecture 13 - Root Space Decomposition II Lecture 13 - Root Space Decomposition II October 18, 2012 1 Review First let us recall the situation. Let g be a simple algebra, with maximal toral subalgebra h (which we are calling a CSA, or Cartan Subalgebra).

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Tridiagonal matrices. Gérard MEURANT. October, 2008

Tridiagonal matrices. Gérard MEURANT. October, 2008 Tridiagonal matrices Gérard MEURANT October, 2008 1 Similarity 2 Cholesy factorizations 3 Eigenvalues 4 Inverse Similarity Let α 1 ω 1 β 1 α 2 ω 2 T =......... β 2 α 1 ω 1 β 1 α and β i ω i, i = 1,...,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Memoirs on Differential Equations and Mathematical Physics

Memoirs on Differential Equations and Mathematical Physics Memoirs on Differential Equations and Mathematical Physics Volume 31, 2004, 83 97 T. Tadumadze and L. Alkhazishvili FORMULAS OF VARIATION OF SOLUTION FOR NON-LINEAR CONTROLLED DELAY DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

A Two-Sided Laplace Inversion Algorithm with Computable Error Bounds and Its Applications in Financial Engineering

A Two-Sided Laplace Inversion Algorithm with Computable Error Bounds and Its Applications in Financial Engineering Electronic Companion A Two-Sie Laplace Inversion Algorithm with Computable Error Bouns an Its Applications in Financial Engineering Ning Cai, S. G. Kou, Zongjian Liu HKUST an Columbia University Appenix

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

D Alembert s Solution to the Wave Equation

D Alembert s Solution to the Wave Equation D Alembert s Solution to the Wave Equation MATH 467 Partial Differential Equations J. Robert Buchanan Department of Mathematics Fall 2018 Objectives In this lesson we will learn: a change of variable technique

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

SCITECH Volume 13, Issue 2 RESEARCH ORGANISATION Published online: March 29, 2018

SCITECH Volume 13, Issue 2 RESEARCH ORGANISATION Published online: March 29, 2018 Journal of rogressive Research in Mathematics(JRM) ISSN: 2395-028 SCITECH Volume 3, Issue 2 RESEARCH ORGANISATION ublished online: March 29, 208 Journal of rogressive Research in Mathematics www.scitecresearch.com/journals

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Matrices and Determinants

Matrices and Determinants Matrices and Determinants SUBJECTIVE PROBLEMS: Q 1. For what value of k do the following system of equations possess a non-trivial (i.e., not all zero) solution over the set of rationals Q? x + ky + 3z

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Homomorphism in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Automata

Homomorphism in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Automata International Journal of Fuzzy Mathematics Systems. ISSN 2248-9940 Volume 3, Number 1 (2013), pp. 39-45 Research India Publications http://www.ripublication.com/ijfms.htm Homomorphism in Intuitionistic

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

3.4 SUM AND DIFFERENCE FORMULAS. NOTE: cos(α+β) cos α + cos β cos(α-β) cos α -cos β

3.4 SUM AND DIFFERENCE FORMULAS. NOTE: cos(α+β) cos α + cos β cos(α-β) cos α -cos β 3.4 SUM AND DIFFERENCE FORMULAS Page Theorem cos(αβ cos α cos β -sin α cos(α-β cos α cos β sin α NOTE: cos(αβ cos α cos β cos(α-β cos α -cos β Proof of cos(α-β cos α cos β sin α Let s use a unit circle

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Generating Set of the Complete Semigroups of Binary Relations

Generating Set of the Complete Semigroups of Binary Relations Applied Mathematics 06 7 98-07 Published Online January 06 in SciRes http://wwwscirporg/journal/am http://dxdoiorg/036/am067009 Generating Set of the Complete Semigroups of Binary Relations Yasha iasamidze

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

HOMEWORK 4 = G. In order to plot the stress versus the stretch we define a normalized stretch:

HOMEWORK 4 = G. In order to plot the stress versus the stretch we define a normalized stretch: HOMEWORK 4 Problem a For the fast loading case, we want to derive the relationship between P zz and λ z. We know that the nominal stress is expressed as: P zz = ψ λ z where λ z = λ λ z. Therefore, applying

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Problem Set 3: Solutions

Problem Set 3: Solutions CMPSCI 69GG Applied Information Theory Fall 006 Problem Set 3: Solutions. [Cover and Thomas 7.] a Define the following notation, C I p xx; Y max X; Y C I p xx; Ỹ max I X; Ỹ We would like to show that C

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

MINIMAL CLOSED SETS AND MAXIMAL CLOSED SETS

MINIMAL CLOSED SETS AND MAXIMAL CLOSED SETS MINIMAL CLOSED SETS AND MAXIMAL CLOSED SETS FUMIE NAKAOKA AND NOBUYUKI ODA Received 20 December 2005; Revised 28 May 2006; Accepted 6 August 2006 Some properties of minimal closed sets and maximal closed

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Homework 8 Model Solution Section

Homework 8 Model Solution Section MATH 004 Homework Solution Homework 8 Model Solution Section 14.5 14.6. 14.5. Use the Chain Rule to find dz where z cosx + 4y), x 5t 4, y 1 t. dz dx + dy y sinx + 4y)0t + 4) sinx + 4y) 1t ) 0t + 4t ) sinx

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES G11LMA Linear Mathematics Examination Solutions

SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES G11LMA Linear Mathematics Examination Solutions SCHOOL OF MATHEMATICAL SCIENCES GLMA Linear Mathematics 00- Examination Solutions. (a) i. ( + 5i)( i) = (6 + 5) + (5 )i = + i. Real part is, imaginary part is. (b) ii. + 5i i ( + 5i)( + i) = ( i)( + i)

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Jesse Maassen and Mark Lundstrom Purdue University November 25, 2013

Jesse Maassen and Mark Lundstrom Purdue University November 25, 2013 Notes on Average Scattering imes and Hall Factors Jesse Maassen and Mar Lundstrom Purdue University November 5, 13 I. Introduction 1 II. Solution of the BE 1 III. Exercises: Woring out average scattering

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates Kiryl Tsishchanka Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates In this section we develop the formula for the area of a region whose boundary is given by a polar equation. We need to use the formula for the

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Srednicki Chapter 55

Srednicki Chapter 55 Srednicki Chapter 55 QFT Problems & Solutions A. George August 3, 03 Srednicki 55.. Use equations 55.3-55.0 and A i, A j ] = Π i, Π j ] = 0 (at equal times) to verify equations 55.-55.3. This is our third

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

THE SECOND ISOMORPHISM THEOREM ON ORDERED SET UNDER ANTIORDERS. Daniel A. Romano

THE SECOND ISOMORPHISM THEOREM ON ORDERED SET UNDER ANTIORDERS. Daniel A. Romano 235 Kragujevac J. Math. 30 (2007) 235 242. THE SECOND ISOMORPHISM THEOREM ON ORDERED SET UNDER ANTIORDERS Daniel A. Romano Department of Mathematics and Informatics, Banja Luka University, Mladena Stojanovića

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Lecture 2. Soundness and completeness of propositional logic

Lecture 2. Soundness and completeness of propositional logic Lecture 2 Soundness and completeness of propositional logic February 9, 2004 1 Overview Review of natural deduction. Soundness and completeness. Semantics of propositional formulas. Soundness proof. Completeness

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

5. Choice under Uncertainty

5. Choice under Uncertainty 5. Choice under Uncertainty Daisuke Oyama Microeconomics I May 23, 2018 Formulations von Neumann-Morgenstern (1944/1947) X: Set of prizes Π: Set of probability distributions on X : Preference relation

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

2. Let H 1 and H 2 be Hilbert spaces and let T : H 1 H 2 be a bounded linear operator. Prove that [T (H 1 )] = N (T ). (6p)

2. Let H 1 and H 2 be Hilbert spaces and let T : H 1 H 2 be a bounded linear operator. Prove that [T (H 1 )] = N (T ). (6p) Uppsala Universitet Matematiska Institutionen Andreas Strömbergsson Prov i matematik Funktionalanalys Kurs: F3B, F4Sy, NVP 2005-03-08 Skrivtid: 9 14 Tillåtna hjälpmedel: Manuella skrivdon, Kreyszigs bok

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Exercises 10. Find a fundamental matrix of the given system of equations. Also find the fundamental matrix Φ(t) satisfying Φ(0) = I. 1.

Exercises 10. Find a fundamental matrix of the given system of equations. Also find the fundamental matrix Φ(t) satisfying Φ(0) = I. 1. Exercises 0 More exercises are available in Elementary Differential Equations. If you have a problem to solve any of them, feel free to come to office hour. Problem Find a fundamental matrix of the given

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Lecture 15 - Root System Axiomatics

Lecture 15 - Root System Axiomatics Lecture 15 - Root System Axiomatics Nov 1, 01 In this lecture we examine root systems from an axiomatic point of view. 1 Reflections If v R n, then it determines a hyperplane, denoted P v, through the

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Econ 2110: Fall 2008 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8 questions or comments to Dan Fetter 1

Econ 2110: Fall 2008 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8  questions or comments to Dan Fetter 1 Eon : Fall 8 Suggested Solutions to Problem Set 8 Email questions or omments to Dan Fetter Problem. Let X be a salar with density f(x, θ) (θx + θ) [ x ] with θ. (a) Find the most powerful level α test

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Second Order Partial Differential Equations

Second Order Partial Differential Equations Chapter 7 Second Order Partial Differential Equations 7.1 Introduction A second order linear PDE in two independent variables (x, y Ω can be written as A(x, y u x + B(x, y u xy + C(x, y u u u + D(x, y

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Commutative Monoids in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Sets

Commutative Monoids in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Sets Commutative Monoids in Intuitionistic Fuzzy Sets S K Mala #1, Dr. MM Shanmugapriya *2 1 PhD Scholar in Mathematics, Karpagam University, Coimbatore, Tamilnadu- 641021 Assistant Professor of Mathematics,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Bayesian statistics. DS GA 1002 Probability and Statistics for Data Science.

Bayesian statistics. DS GA 1002 Probability and Statistics for Data Science. Bayesian statistics DS GA 1002 Probability and Statistics for Data Science http://www.cims.nyu.edu/~cfgranda/pages/dsga1002_fall17 Carlos Fernandez-Granda Frequentist vs Bayesian statistics In frequentist

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

P AND P. P : actual probability. P : risk neutral probability. Realtionship: mutual absolute continuity P P. For example:

P AND P. P : actual probability. P : risk neutral probability. Realtionship: mutual absolute continuity P P. For example: (B t, S (t) t P AND P,..., S (p) t ): securities P : actual probability P : risk neutral probability Realtionship: mutual absolute continuity P P For example: P : ds t = µ t S t dt + σ t S t dw t P : ds

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Finite Field Problems: Solutions

Finite Field Problems: Solutions Finite Field Problems: Solutions 1. Let f = x 2 +1 Z 11 [x] and let F = Z 11 [x]/(f), a field. Let Solution: F =11 2 = 121, so F = 121 1 = 120. The possible orders are the divisors of 120. Solution: The

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Congruence Classes of Invertible Matrices of Order 3 over F 2

Congruence Classes of Invertible Matrices of Order 3 over F 2 International Journal of Algebra, Vol. 8, 24, no. 5, 239-246 HIKARI Ltd, www.m-hikari.com http://dx.doi.org/.2988/ija.24.422 Congruence Classes of Invertible Matrices of Order 3 over F 2 Ligong An and

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Coefficient Inequalities for a New Subclass of K-uniformly Convex Functions

Coefficient Inequalities for a New Subclass of K-uniformly Convex Functions International Journal of Computational Science and Mathematics. ISSN 0974-89 Volume, Number (00), pp. 67--75 International Research Publication House http://www.irphouse.com Coefficient Inequalities for

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

The Simply Typed Lambda Calculus

The Simply Typed Lambda Calculus Type Inference Instead of writing type annotations, can we use an algorithm to infer what the type annotations should be? That depends on the type system. For simple type systems the answer is yes, and

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates

Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates Kiryl Tsishchanka Areas and Lengths in Polar Coordinates In this section we develop the formula for the area of a region whose boundary is given by a polar equation. We need to use the formula for the

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Parametrized Surfaces

Parametrized Surfaces Parametrized Surfaces Recall from our unit on vector-valued functions at the beginning of the semester that an R 3 -valued function c(t) in one parameter is a mapping of the form c : I R 3 where I is some

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Bounding Nonsplitting Enumeration Degrees

Bounding Nonsplitting Enumeration Degrees Bounding Nonsplitting Enumeration Degrees Thomas F. Kent Andrea Sorbi Università degli Studi di Siena Italia July 18, 2007 Goal: Introduce a form of Σ 0 2-permitting for the enumeration degrees. Till now,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Credit Risk. Finance and Insurance - Stochastic Analysis and Practical Methods Spring School Jena, March 2009

Credit Risk. Finance and Insurance - Stochastic Analysis and Practical Methods Spring School Jena, March 2009 Credit Risk. Finance and Insurance - Stochastic Analysis and Practical Methods Spring School Jena, March 2009 1 IV. Hedging of credit derivatives 1. Two default free assets, one defaultable asset 1.1 Two

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Lecture 21: Properties and robustness of LSE

Lecture 21: Properties and robustness of LSE Lecture 21: Properties and robustness of LSE BLUE: Robustness of LSE against normality We now study properties of l τ β and σ 2 under assumption A2, i.e., without the normality assumption on ε. From Theorem

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Approximation of distance between locations on earth given by latitude and longitude

Approximation of distance between locations on earth given by latitude and longitude Approximation of distance between locations on earth given by latitude and longitude Jan Behrens 2012-12-31 In this paper we shall provide a method to approximate distances between two points on earth

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

( y) Partial Differential Equations

( y) Partial Differential Equations Partial Dierential Equations Linear P.D.Es. contains no owers roducts o the deendent variables / an o its derivatives can occasionall be solved. Consider eamle ( ) a (sometimes written as a ) we can integrate

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

A Bonus-Malus System as a Markov Set-Chain. Małgorzata Niemiec Warsaw School of Economics Institute of Econometrics

A Bonus-Malus System as a Markov Set-Chain. Małgorzata Niemiec Warsaw School of Economics Institute of Econometrics A Bonus-Malus System as a Markov Set-Chain Małgorzata Niemiec Warsaw School of Economics Institute of Econometrics Contents 1. Markov set-chain 2. Model of bonus-malus system 3. Example 4. Conclusions

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Optimal Parameter in Hermitian and Skew-Hermitian Splitting Method for Certain Two-by-Two Block Matrices

Optimal Parameter in Hermitian and Skew-Hermitian Splitting Method for Certain Two-by-Two Block Matrices Optimal Parameter in Hermitian and Skew-Hermitian Splitting Method for Certain Two-by-Two Block Matrices Chi-Kwong Li Department of Mathematics The College of William and Mary Williamsburg, Virginia 23187-8795

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

A Note on Intuitionistic Fuzzy. Equivalence Relation

A Note on Intuitionistic Fuzzy. Equivalence Relation International Mathematical Forum, 5, 2010, no. 67, 3301-3307 A Note on Intuitionistic Fuzzy Equivalence Relation D. K. Basnet Dept. of Mathematics, Assam University Silchar-788011, Assam, India dkbasnet@rediffmail.com

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

STAT200C: Hypothesis Testing

STAT200C: Hypothesis Testing STAT200C: Hypothesis Testing Zhaoxia Yu Spring 2017 Some Definitions A hypothesis is a statement about a population parameter. The two complementary hypotheses in a hypothesis testing are the null hypothesis

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Quadratic Expressions

Quadratic Expressions Quadratic Expressions. The standard form of a quadratic equation is ax + bx + c = 0 where a, b, c R and a 0. The roots of ax + bx + c = 0 are b ± b a 4ac. 3. For the equation ax +bx+c = 0, sum of the roots

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

ANSWERSHEET (TOPIC = DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS) COLLECTION #2. h 0 h h 0 h h 0 ( ) g k = g 0 + g 1 + g g 2009 =?

ANSWERSHEET (TOPIC = DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS) COLLECTION #2. h 0 h h 0 h h 0 ( ) g k = g 0 + g 1 + g g 2009 =? Teko Classes IITJEE/AIEEE Maths by SUHAAG SIR, Bhopal, Ph (0755) 3 00 000 www.tekoclasses.com ANSWERSHEET (TOPIC DIFFERENTIAL CALCULUS) COLLECTION # Question Type A.Single Correct Type Q. (A) Sol least

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Chapter 3: Ordinal Numbers

Chapter 3: Ordinal Numbers Chapter 3: Ordinal Numbers There are two kinds of number.. Ordinal numbers (0th), st, 2nd, 3rd, 4th, 5th,..., ω, ω +,... ω2, ω2+,... ω 2... answers to the question What position is... in a sequence? What

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Probability and Random Processes (Part II)

Probability and Random Processes (Part II) Probability and Random Processes (Part II) 1. If the variance σ x of d(n) = x(n) x(n 1) is one-tenth the variance σ x of a stationary zero-mean discrete-time signal x(n), then the normalized autocorrelation

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Second Order RLC Filters

Second Order RLC Filters ECEN 60 Circuits/Electronics Spring 007-0-07 P. Mathys Second Order RLC Filters RLC Lowpass Filter A passive RLC lowpass filter (LPF) circuit is shown in the following schematic. R L C v O (t) Using phasor

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

DiracDelta. Notations. Primary definition. Specific values. General characteristics. Traditional name. Traditional notation

DiracDelta. Notations. Primary definition. Specific values. General characteristics. Traditional name. Traditional notation DiracDelta Notations Traditional name Dirac delta function Traditional notation x Mathematica StandardForm notation DiracDeltax Primary definition 4.03.02.000.0 x Π lim ε ; x ε0 x 2 2 ε Specific values

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

The semiclassical Garding inequality

The semiclassical Garding inequality The semiclassical Garding inequality We give a proof of the semiclassical Garding inequality (Theorem 4.1 using as the only black box the Calderon-Vaillancourt Theorem. 1 Anti-Wick quantization For (q,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

6.1. Dirac Equation. Hamiltonian. Dirac Eq.

6.1. Dirac Equation. Hamiltonian. Dirac Eq. 6.1. Dirac Equation Ref: M.Kaku, Quantum Field Theory, Oxford Univ Press (1993) η μν = η μν = diag(1, -1, -1, -1) p 0 = p 0 p = p i = -p i p μ p μ = p 0 p 0 + p i p i = E c 2 - p 2 = (m c) 2 H = c p 2

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

MA 342N Assignment 1 Due 24 February 2016

MA 342N Assignment 1 Due 24 February 2016 M 342N ssignment Due 24 February 206 Id: 342N-s206-.m4,v. 206/02/5 2:25:36 john Exp john. Suppose that q, in addition to satisfying the assumptions from lecture, is an even function. Prove that η(λ = 0,

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

CRASH COURSE IN PRECALCULUS

CRASH COURSE IN PRECALCULUS CRASH COURSE IN PRECALCULUS Shiah-Sen Wang The graphs are prepared by Chien-Lun Lai Based on : Precalculus: Mathematics for Calculus by J. Stuwart, L. Redin & S. Watson, 6th edition, 01, Brooks/Cole Chapter

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Limit theorems under sublinear expectations and probabilities

Limit theorems under sublinear expectations and probabilities Limit theorems under sublinear expectations and probabilities Xinpeng LI Shandong University & Université Paris 1 Young Researchers Meeting on BSDEs, Numerics and Finance 4 July, Oxford 1 / 25 Outline

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

If we restrict the domain of y = sin x to [ π, π ], the restrict function. y = sin x, π 2 x π 2

If we restrict the domain of y = sin x to [ π, π ], the restrict function. y = sin x, π 2 x π 2 Chapter 3. Analytic Trigonometry 3.1 The inverse sine, cosine, and tangent functions 1. Review: Inverse function (1) f 1 (f(x)) = x for every x in the domain of f and f(f 1 (x)) = x for every x in the

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Additional Results for the Pareto/NBD Model

Additional Results for the Pareto/NBD Model Additional Results for the Pareto/NBD Model Peter S. Fader www.petefader.com Bruce G. S. Hardie www.brucehardie.com January 24 Abstract This note derives expressions for i) the raw moments of the posterior

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

Iterated trilinear fourier integrals with arbitrary symbols

Iterated trilinear fourier integrals with arbitrary symbols Cornell University ICM 04, Satellite Conference in Harmonic Analysis, Chosun University, Gwangju, Korea August 6, 04 Motivation the Coifman-Meyer theorem with classical paraproduct(979) B(f, f )(x) :=

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

ECE598: Information-theoretic methods in high-dimensional statistics Spring 2016

ECE598: Information-theoretic methods in high-dimensional statistics Spring 2016 ECE598: Information-theoretic methods in high-dimensional statistics Spring 06 Lecture 7: Information bound Lecturer: Yihong Wu Scribe: Shiyu Liang, Feb 6, 06 [Ed. Mar 9] Recall the Chi-squared divergence

Διαβάστε περισσότερα

557: MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS II RESULTS FROM CLASSICAL HYPOTHESIS TESTING

557: MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS II RESULTS FROM CLASSICAL HYPOTHESIS TESTING Most Powerful Tests 557: MATHEMATICAL STATISTICS II RESULTS FROM CLASSICAL HYPOTHESIS TESTING To construct and assess the quality of a statistical test, we consider the power function β(θ). Consider a

Διαβάστε περισσότερα